![]() |
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | |
England and Wales High Court (Queen's Bench Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales High Court (Queen's Bench Division) Decisions >> Ageas (UK) Ltd v Kwik-Fit (GB) Ltd & Anor [2014] EWHC 2178 (QB) (04 July 2014) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/QB/2014/2178.html Cite as: [2014] EWHC 2178 (QB), [2014] WLR(D) 407, [2014] BUS LR 1338, [2014] Bus LR 1338 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [View ICLR summary: [2014] WLR(D) 407] [Buy ICLR report: [2014] Bus LR 1338] [Help]
QUEEN'S BENCH DIVISION
7 Rolls Building, Fetter Lane London, EC4A 1NL |
||
B e f o r e :
____________________
Ageas (UK) Limited |
Claimant |
|
- and - |
||
Kwik-Fit (GB) Limited AIG Europe Limited |
Defendants |
____________________
Patricia Robertson QC and Tamara Oppenheimer (instructed by CMS Cameron McKenna LLP) for the Second Defendant
Hearing dates: 9-13 & 17 June 2014
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
The Hon. Mr Justice Popplewell :
Introduction
The background
The issues
Discussion
"Although the 1990 management accounts did not show a true and fair view because rebate reserves were overstated by £1.7m., in order to see if the plaintiff has suffered any loss and, if so, how it should be quantified, it is necessary to establish the actual profit for that year. Thus, if some credit or profit has been omitted which can properly be taken into account in the 1990 profit, the apparent loss is pro tanto extinguished or diminished. For this purpose, in our judgment, it is permissible to take into account hindsight to arrive at the actual figures."
"[132] Before I move on from this part of my judgment, there is a more general point which I wish to make. So far I have looked at the question of the quantum of any loss in the way in which the experts looked at it, making hypothetical estimates both of the but for valuation and of the actual valuation. Both experts were at pains to leave hindsight out of account in both of their valuations. That is plainly correct as regards the but for valuation, which is a hypothetical exercise, but I question whether it is also correct as regards the actual valuation. The actual valuation is not a hypothetical valuation like, for example, a valuation made for capital gains tax or inheritance tax purposes. It is designed to establish what the true loss to Infiniteland has been. Why should hindsight be excluded in that context?
[133] In Mr Downes' written closing submissions he wrote:
"Mr Palmer's evidence is that the actual value was nil. Given the absence of a track record and recent historic losses, it is submitted that Mr Palmer's opinion has an inherent probability about it."
I agree with that, but I am in any event inclined to go further. Infiniteland bought the companies in July 2001, and within a matter of months Bickerton's trade collapsed. Although I do not believe that Artisan realised how bad things were at the time, and although I accept that Artisan would have preferred Infiniteland to make a success of Bickerton, I think that it is obvious now - admittedly with hindsight - that Bickerton was doomed from the time that Infiniteland acquired it. I would in any event agree with Infiniteland (and its expert witness, Mr Palmer) that Bickerton was worthless at the time of acquisition, but even if I was uncertain about that I do not see why I should close my eyes to the undoubted facts that the companies for which Infiniteland agreed to pay over £1.4m turned out in the event to be completely worthless. There were a few hearsay suggestions in the evidence that Mr Aviss milked Bickerton during his brief period in control, so that the failure of Bickerton may have been Mr Aviss's fault, but the point was not pressed, and I repeat my view that Bickerton was doomed from the start.
[134] I do not need hindsight to come to my conclusion, but as a generalisation and subject to principles of remoteness of damage in contract or in tort (which do not in my view arise in this case), losses recoverable in damages are quantified at what they turn out in the event to have been, not at what they might have been forecast to be at the time of the transaction which subsequently goes wrong. Given my earlier conclusions on liability this does not help Infiniteland, but if I had taken a different view on liability, then either without or with hindsight I would agree with Mr Downes and Mr Palmer that the actual valuation of the companies which Infiniteland acquired — the valuation which falls to be compared with the but for valuation of some £1.4m — was nil."
(1) Damages for breach of contract are intended to put the innocent party in the same financial position as if the contract had been performed. This is the compensatory principle which "has been enunciated and applied times without number and is not in doubt" per Lord Bingham in Golden Strait Corpn v Nippon Kubisha Kaisha (The Golden Victory) [2007] 2 AC 353 at [9] (see also per Lord Scott at [29]). It may also be expressed as the claimant being entitled to the value in money of the contractual rights he has lost (per Lord Scott at [30]). The lodestar is that the damages should represent the value of the contractual benefits of which the claimant is deprived by the breach of contract, no less but also not more (per Lord Scott at [36]).
(2) Damages for breach of contract will normally be assessed by reference to the position at the date of breach. But a later date may be used for the assessment if in all the circumstances of the case to do so would more accurately reflect the overriding compensatory principle: County Personnel (Employment Agency) Ltd v Alan R Pulver & Co [1987] 1 WLR 916, at 925-6; The Golden Victory at [11] and the authorities there cited.
"[36] The same would, in my opinion, be true of any anticipatory breach the acceptance of which had terminated an executory contract. The contractual benefit for the loss of which the victim of the breach can seek compensation cannot escape the uncertainties of the future. If, at the time the assessment of damages takes place, there were nothing to suggest that the expected benefit of the executory contract would not, if the contract had remained on foot, have duly accrued, then the quantum of damages would be unaffected by uncertainties that would be no more than conceptual. If there were a real possibility that an event would happen terminating the contract, or in some way reducing the contractual benefit to which the damages claimant would, if the contract had remained on foot, have become entitled, then the quantum of damages might need, in order to reflect the extent of the chance that that possibility might materialise, to be reduced proportionately. The lodestar is that the damages should represent the value of the contractual benefits of which the claimant had been deprived by the breach of contract, no less but also no more. But if a terminating event had happened, speculation would not be needed, an estimate of the extent of the chance of such a happening would no longer be necessary and, in relation to the period during which the contract would have remained executory had it not been for the terminating event, it would be apparent that the earlier anticipatory breach of contract had deprived the victim of the breach of nothing.
………
[38] The arguments of the owners offend the compensatory principle. They are seeking compensation exceeding the value of the contractual benefits of which they were deprived. Their case requires the assessor to speculate about what might happen over the period 17 December 2001 to 6 December 2005 regarding the occurrence of a clause 33 event and to shut his eyes to the actual happening of a clause 33 event in March 2003. The argued justification for thus offending the compensatory principle is that priority should be given to the so-called principle of certainty. My Lords, there is, in my opinion, no such principle. Certainty is a desideratum and a very important one, particularly in commercial contracts. But it is not a principle and must give way to principle. Otherwise incoherence of principle is the likely result. The achievement of certainty in relation to commercial contracts depends, I would suggest, on firm and settled principles of the law of contract rather than on the tailoring of principle in order to frustrate tactics of delay to which many litigants in many areas of litigation are wont to resort. Be that as it may, the compensatory principle that must underlie awards of contractual damages is, in my opinion, clear and requires the appeal in the case to be dismissed."
Lord Brown said:
"[78] …My more fundamental conclusion, as I shall shortly explain, is that the breach date rule does not require contingencies - such as the likely effect of a suspensive condition – to be judged prior to the date when damages finally come to be assessed. ……..Could it really be thought to be in the interests of certainty to address these questions prior to that on which damages are in fact being assessed? To my mind not. Must the judge really shut his eyes to the known facts and speculate how matters might have looked at some earlier date? Again, not without compelling reason and none appears to me. Lord Bingham, at para 12, and Lord Carswell, at para 65, have already explained the "Bwllfa principle": Bwllfa and Merthyr Dare Steam Collieries (1891) Ltd v Pontypridd Waterworks Co [1903] AC 426. There is no need to repeat it. Suffice it to say that I see no good reason to depart from it here."
"If the question goes to arbitration, the arbitrator's duty is to determine the amount of compensation payable. In order to enable him to come to a just and true conclusion it is his duty, I think, to avail himself of all the information at hand at the time of making his award which may be laid before him. Why should he listen to conjecture on a matter which has become an accomplished fact? Why should he guess when he can calculate? With the light before him, why should he shut his eyes and grope in the dark? The mine owner prevented from working his minerals is to be fully compensated – the Act says so. That means that so far as money can compensate him he is to be placed in the position he would have been if he had been free to go on working."
Lord Robertson said at p. 432 that "estimate and conjecture are superseded by facts as the proper media concludendi" and at p. 433 that "as in this instance facts are available, they are not to be shut out."
"My Lords, I think in this case that Phillimore J. stated the question for debate with perfect accuracy when he said that "the true inquiry here is not what is the value of the coalfield or of the coal, but what would the colliery company, if they had not been prohibited, have made out of the coal during the time it would have taken them to get it."
In carefully distinguishing the sale analogy as a false one, the House of Lords might be thought to have endorsed the conclusion of the Court of Appeal on the question had the analogy been a good one, which was that subsequent fluctuations in coal prices would have been irrelevant to a valuation if there had been a sale. But Romer LJ, at least, thought that there was no objection in principle or conceptual difficulty in using subsequent events as an aid to valuation at the earlier date, although in common with the other members of the Court he did not regard subsequent fluctuations in coal prices as assisting in that exercise. He said at p. 141:
"….it is common ground that the compensation to be awarded by the umpire was the true value of the coal on October 15, the day on which notice to treat was given. I agree that in ascertaining that value the umpire may look at facts occurring subsequent to the notice to treat so far as they are material as shewing what was the value of the coal on that date, but not for any other purpose."
"[Ageas] shall, and to the extent reasonably possible shall cause [KFFS] to, act at all times as if uninsured and take all action reasonably necessary or advisable to mitigate any [insured loss] or potential [insured loss]."
Application
Windfall
Allocation of risk
(1) The total volume of business which Ageas aims to write will depend upon its pricing strategy, upon its target customer base, and upon its administrative and cost structures. There is, for example, a spectrum between high volume low premium/margin business and lower volume business with higher premiums and margins. It is for the business under Ageas' ownership to decide where to seek to position itself. The volume of business written following acquisition will in part be the result of Ageas' own strategy in running the business. Further, whatever Ageas' strategy in these respects, the insurance market and wider macro economic circumstances are likely also to have an effect on the number of policies written. These may influence Ageas' market share, the level of premiums and margins, and possibly the size of the market as a whole in a recession.
(2) The mix of business, and in particular the number of instalment policies written, again may be the result of the way Ageas chooses to run the business in a number of respects. A higher number of instalment contracts might increase the incidence of TOCBD; but it brings with it an increase in the opportunity for finance income, and for add on products. Conversely, as already observed, a reduction in the number of instalment contracts might bring a welcome reduction in TOCBD but an unwelcome reduction in finance income. Whatever Ageas' strategy in these respects, again the insurance market and wider macro economic circumstances may have an effect on the number of instalment policies written.
(3) Ageas may take steps to reduce the incidence of cancellation of policies, which again may have ramifications for other parts of the business model. The evidence suggested that cancellation rates tend to be lower for lower premium business and the evidence of Mr Gilmurray, KFIS' Finance Director since May 2011, was that one of the reasons TOCBD amounts fell after acquisition was a fall in premium rates. Lower premium business could be part of a business strategy or the effect of market influences or both. Lower premiums might lead to a reduction in TOCBD through a lower cancellation rate, but any such benefit would be offset or outweighed by the consequences in lower revenues or profit margins.
(4) The number of cancelling policyholders who default on the debt may be capable of being influenced by the company's administrative arrangements and credit risk inquiries, but may also be a product of macro economic conditions. One might expect more defaulters in a recession.
(5) The efficient management of TOCBD may be down to the way Ageas runs the business; it may also be a function of the regulatory environment and terms and conditions available from insurers.
Conclusion