BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?

No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!



BAILII [Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback]

High Court of Ireland Decisions


You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> High Court of Ireland Decisions >> Blemings v. David Patton Ltd. [1997] IEHC 191; [2001] 1 IR 385 (15th January, 1997)
URL: http://www.bailii.org/ie/cases/IEHC/1997/191.html
Cite as: [2001] 1 IR 385, [1997] IEHC 191

[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]


Blemings v. David Patton Ltd. [1997] IEHC 191; [2001] 1 IR 385 (15th January, 1997)

THE HIGH COURT
RECORD NO. 2881P/1994
BETWEEN
JIM BLEMINGS AND ORS.
(AS PER SCHEDULE ATTACHED TO THE PLENARY SUMMONS)
PLAINTIFFS
AND
DAVID PATTON LIMITED, EDWARD KAVANAGH, (MAYNOOTH) LIMITED,
PAUL & VINCENT LIMITED, JOHN THOMPSON AND SONS LIMITED AND MONAGHAN POULTRY PRODUCTS LIMITED
DEFENDANTS

Judgment delivered by The Honourable Mr. Justice Shanley on Wednesday the 15th day of January 1997

(1) THE PARTIES

1. The 47 Plaintiffs in this Action grow chickens for the Defendant, Monaghan Poultry Products Limited. All of the Plaintiffs reside in the County of Monaghan, and the first named Defendant (herein referred to as 'MPP'), carries on it's business from premises on the outskirts of the town of Monaghan. The agreements between each of the Plaintiffs and MPP, whereby the Plaintiffs grow chickens for MPP, have never been reduced to writing: I shall return to the detail of these contractual relationships later, but, for the present, I shall identify only three elements:

(i) the Plaintiffs are not permitted to purchase chicken feed other than through MPP.
(ii) the Plaintiffs are paid a price by MPP by reference to live chicken weight received from a Plaintiff grower by MPP after deductions have been made by MPP for feedstuffs supplied by millers and other items.
(iii) the Plaintiffs are not paid for chickens received by MPP from growers which are classified as "dead or useless".

(2) THE ISSUES

2. The Plaintiff growers contend:-


(a) That each of the agreements between the growers and MPP, whereby they, as growers, are not permitted to purchase meal directly from the millers who make such meal, infringes Section 4 of the Competition Act, 1991.
(b) That each of the agreements between MPP and certain Millers whereby those millers agree not to supply the Plaintiff growers other than through MPP also offends Section 4 of the 1991 Act.
(c) That each of the agreements between the Plaintiff growers and MPP impose unfair selling prices upon the growers selling chicken flesh to MPP and, in consequence, infringe Section 4 of the 1991 Act.
(d) That each of the agreements between the Plaintiffs and MPP, apart from infringing Section 4 in the foregoing and certain other respects, permits MPP to impose unfair purchase prices and makes the conclusion of the agreements subject to the acceptance by the growers of a supplementary obligation (namely the purchase of feed from MPP) which "by its nature" or according to "commercial usage" has not any connection with the agreement, thereby abusing a dominant position in the market for the supply of broiler growing services in breach of Section 5 of the Competition Act, 1991.
(e) That MPP has acted in a price discriminating manner in its dealings with growers thereby infringing both Sections 4 and 5 of the 1991 Act.
(f) That the contractual relationship between each of the Plaintiffs and MPP imposed an obligation on MPP to act in a fair and equitable manner in its dealings with each of the Plaintiffs and that in misstating, exaggerating, or failing to properly account to each of the Plaintiffs in respect of dead and useless birds, it was in breach of its agreement with each of the Plaintiffs.
(g) That all of the foregoing infringements, or breaches, entitle the Plaintiffs and each of them to an account and/or damages.

3. While the Defence delivered by MPP traversed each and every allegation contained in the Statement of Claim delivered by the Plaintiff growers, it can be said that, at the trial of this Action, the following were the matters strongly put in issue by MPP:-


(i) That they have infringed either Sections 4 or 5 of the Competition Act, 1991.
(ii) That they were in breach of any contractual obligation owed to the Plaintiff growers.
(iii) In particular, that they occupy a dominant position in the alleged or any product market, or if they do, that they have abused such a position.
(iv) Additionally, that the requirement to purchase feedstuffs through MPP and the purchase prices offered by MPP for live chicken flesh were matters which could be regarded as infringements of the Competition Act, 1991.
(v) That, even if breaches of contract or infringement of the 1991 Act were established, the Plaintiffs had made out a claim for any special damages.

4. There was one matter of importance on which the Plaintiffs and MPP agreed, namely that the relevant product market with which the Court was concerned was the market for the provision of broiler growing services.


(3) THE BROILER INDUSTRY

(i) STRUCTURE

5. The production of broiler chickens for processing comprises a number of stages:

(a) First, it is necessary to rear what are described as "grandparent" stock for the purpose of producing parent stock.
(b) The parent stock are reared on what are called "breeder farms" . These farms are usually independent of any chicken processor but of necessity have contracts for the supply of eggs, either to an 'independent' hatchery owner, or a processor who also has a hatchery.
(c) The hatcheries incubate and hatch the eggs. These eggs can only be held for a maximum of 10 days before commencing the hatching process. Accordingly, a hatchery at any given date will not take more eggs than its anticipated requirement of day old chicks over the next 10 plus 21 days (being the incubation and hatching period). Where a breeder farmer has more eggs than there is a demand for, they are destroyed on his farm. Most of the processors in the Republic of Ireland own their own hatcheries: however, there are two independent hatcheries which supply day old chicks on demand to processors and, occasionally, to growers. Mr. John Mawers, a witness called by MPP, owns his own breeder farm and hatchery. The hatchery produces some 200,000 day old chicks per week. The hatching process is by way of an environmentally controlled machine which, as Mr.. Mawers put it, "takes the place of the old broody hen".
(e) The day old chicks are despatched by the processor to the growers (with whom the processor has contracts) to grow the chickens. These growers feed the chickens in chicken houses especially constructed for that purpose. When fattened, the live chickens are taken to the processor.
(f) The processor, receiving the fattened chickens at the processing plant, stuns, bleeds and passes the chickens along a kill line, where various organs are removed by staff, and birds, deemed unfit for human consumption, are removed by veterinary inspectors from the Department of Agriculture.

(ii) SIZE AND LOCATION

6. There are 98 breeder farms for chicken eggs; some 14 hatcheries (2 of which are independent of processors) 335 growers and 13 processors in the republic of Ireland. The industry is concentrated in 8 counties: Monaghan, Cavan, Limerick, Cork, Waterford, Galway, Mayo and Roscommon. Three processors do business in the Cavan Monaghan area: they are MPP, Cartons and Cootehill. the plants of Cartons and Cootehill are in County Cavan, but all three processors have most of their growers located in Monaghan. Mr. Quigley, one of the Plaintiffs, estimated that MPP will produce 46% of the processed chicken flesh in the Cavan-Monaghan area in 1996, with Cartons producing 45%, and Cootehill 9%. Ms. Breda O'Driscoll, a director of MPP, gave evidence that MPP's share of the Monaghan "market" was 34%; of the regional market (Cavan, Monaghan, Louth and Meath) 21%, and nationally 16.3%. It is to be noted that Mr. Quigley's figures cannot be compared with Ms. O'Driscoll's: his figures represent an estimate of the share of binds processed by the three processors in 1996, whereas Mrs. O'Driscoll's figures are representative of market share on the basis of sales in each region and not necessarily for 1996 - though prepared in that year.

(iii) PROCESSORS AND MARKET TRENDS

7. In 1993, according to Mrs. O'Driscoll, the demand for whole chickens represented 80% of the broiler meat market. This, she says, declined rapidly, such that, by 1995, whole chickens accounted for only 54 or 55% of the market. She explained that this trend was the result of consumer preference for chicken fillets and other portions. The result for MPP, she said, was that instead of having a whole chicken that is just going into a packing department to be put in a plastic bag, fillets now have to be put on trays or bagged depending on customer specification. The new found demand has, according to her, resulted in considerable increased costs such that the benefit of improved prices at retail level had been eliminated in the year 1995 and indeed up to May 1996.


(iv) DISEASE AND MORTALITY

8. Chickens, like all other birds, are susceptible to disease. Broiler growers receive their chicks from eggs produced on breeder farms and are, in the first instance, dependent on the breeders to ensure the health status of these chicks. When the day old chicks arrive at the growing houses, and while they are grown, they can be afflicted by diseases from yolk sack to gumbro, the consequence of which can vary from morbidity to mortality. It was commoncase that the high health status enjoyed by the Irish Avian Industry had all but disappeared by 1993, and that diminution in status has affected vaccination policies and other flock management practices in the industry.


(v) BROILER FEEDS

9. There are about 90 significant feed compounders in the Republic of Ireland and, of that number, only about eight are significant in poultry feed manufacture. Cereals comprise 70% of the poultry feed, and poultry feed comprises some 70% of a grower's costs. Because Ireland is not self sufficient in cereals, the cereal element in the feed is high in cost - influenced by a continuation of intervention prices, the price of imported cereal, as well as transport costs into Ireland. Feed is seen as one of the major risk factors in the spread of disease: chickens are fed on one feed only, and have no access to their own feed; in consequence, it is important that the feed represent a complete and balanced diet. Mr. Wilson, a nutritionist, called by the Defendant, said that, in a broiler feed, there might be 30 or 40 individual components added, per tonne of feed, and that some components might go as low as microgrammes per tonne, but were, nevertheless, essential. Mr. Wilson was of the opinion that the quality of meal also affected the quality of the finished broiler. Apart from the care required in compounding, poultry feed regulations now require that such feed be heat treated to minimise the risk of Salmonella and infectious bronchitis. Both Mr. Wilson and Mr. Truesdale (a miller) gave evidence of the extent to which consumer demand has resulted in large retailers requiring processors to be able to trace the produce right "through the system from purchase of raw material right through to the flesh of the chickens or whatever it is on the shelf"; words such as 'bio security', 'traceability' and 'due diligence' were used by witnesses to indicate a trend whereby a processor selling in the marketplace, if he is to satisfy consumer demands, will have to be able to establish that he can supervise the quality of his product from raw material inputs to finished flesh products. If this is to happen, it is agreed, the processor must ensure, among other things, that there is in place a quality control process where processors can immediately link meal product used to flesh on a supermarket shelf. The link between chicken flesh quality and meal quality was recognised by one of the Plaintiffs, Mr. Quigley, when he said


".. the birds will be the judge of the quality of the meal if we are buying direct"

10. Mr. Quigley was making the case that, if the growers could purchase meal direct from the millers, they could themselves assure quality. In the republic of Ireland, all processors (save one) control the purchase of the meal used by their growers. The only exception is Cootehill, a co-operative society, where the members are the growers, and the society owns the processing plant.



(vi) GROWERS AND PROCESSORS

11. One of the characteristics of the broiler growing industry is that the vast majority of the growers are located within a radius of 15 miles or thereabouts from the processor to whom they supply the fattened chickens. Another feature of the industry is that, while two or more processors are located in the same area (such as MPP, Cartons and Cootehill) there is very little mobility between the growers and the processors. What inferences can be drawn from the spatial distribution of a processor's growers and from the apparent lack of mobility of growers between processors is a matter to which I will return later in this judgment.


12. With the exception of Cootehill, all growers purchase their chicken meal, and day old chicks, from the processors for whom they grow: this is not a matter of choice but a requirement of the processors. Of the growers costs (excluding financing costs) the costs of meal and day olds account for about 92%, with other "on farm" costs of about 8%. The prices charged by MPP for day olds and for meal are deducted by them at the time when they are paying for the live chickens delivered by the growers at MPP's plant.





(vii) BECOMING A GROWER

13. Whatever about the early years of the industry, the evidence established that over the last 20 years there was little or no scope for a person to make the financial investment, required of a grower, without being assured of a processor who would take his fattened chicks. In consequence, becoming a grower depended, in effect, on being so invited by a processor. The major investment for a grower was and is the acquisition of a site and the erection of a chicken house. In 1988 Mr. Quigley, one of the Plaintiffs, erected his chicken house which had a capacity for 20,000 birds at a cost to him of £65,000. It cost him a further £10,000 plus V.A.T. to equip his house. The house, as he described it, was 70 yards long and 16 yards wide and came in a "kit" form and was erected on a concrete base. It contained fibreglass wool all over the structure so that it was totally insulated. It had a store at one end (8 foot by 6 foot) with the rest of the building being open plan with posts down the middle supporting the roof. The house did not have windows but adjustable flaps for ventilation. Ventilation, heaters, feeders and drinkers were all controlled from panels in the store room. The feed was augured from a feed bin outside the house. Mr. Quigley's house was of a kind used by many of the growers.





(vii) THE PROCESSORS

14. Most processors have their own hatcheries but not their own breeder farms. Mr. McGlone, the procurement manager for MPP outlined the planning needed to ensure that MPP, as a processor, could meet consumer demand. At any given time, the hatchery is told the number of eggs to set: the grower is told to expect the arrival of day olds; the growers phone in the daily weights of growing chickens and their meal requirements; MPP ensure delivery of that meal by the designated millers. Each grown receives his batch of "day olds" in rotation and the number of batches varies, annually, between 4 and 6. The growing cycle is about 8 weeks with the processor taking delivery of some of the birds from the grower at around 36 days and 43 days during the cycle. The weight of birds, and customer orders, dictate when exactly during the cycle, birds will be taken in by the processor.


(4) THE PLAINTIFF GROWERS

(i) All of the Plaintiffs still (save Mr. Jack Scott) grow for MPP. The vast majority of them resides and have their chicken houses within a 10 to 15 mile radius of MPP's processing plant. Most of the Plaintiffs are farmers with small holdings whose income is not solely derived from rearing chickens. Most of the Plaintiffs have only one chicken house, but some have more than one. Jack Scott, who grew for MPP up until September, 1994, has 5 houses with a bird capacity of 55,000. Of the Plaintiffs who gave evidence, Mr. Quigley has one house with a capacity for 20,000 birds. Mrs.Treanor has two houses with a capacity for some 46,000 birds; finally Mr. Peter McKenna has two houses.
(ii) The calculation used by all growers as a measure of their profitability is what Mr. Quigley described as "gross margin over feed and chick per 1,000 birds". Mr. Quigley explained that this calculation was the amount payable to him by MPP for 1000 birds less the costs of meal, the costs of the day olds and the cost of other deductions imposed by MPP on the growers. The calculation did not include on farm costs (such as electricity, vaccinations, catching costs etc.) or repayment costs on capital borrowed to pay for and erect chicken houses or equipment.

(5) THE CONTRACTUAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN GROWER AND MPP

15. There was no disagreement between the parties as to what the nature and form of the contractual relationship between the grower and MPP was. There is no written agreement between MPP and the grower. The main features of the relationship, at the date of the institution of the proceedings, were:-


(i) MPP provides day old chicks to a grower at a price determined by MPP.
(ii) MPP provides the grower with meal ordered by that grower at a price determined by MPP
(iii) MPP obtains the meal from one of four designated millers
(iv) the grower cannot purchase his meal directly from these or other millers. Equally, he must purchase his day olds from MPP.
(v) the meal supplied comprises starter crumb, grower meal and finishing meal.
(vi) MPP decide when they wish to take delivery of fattened chickens.
(vii) Growers are required to phone in the weights of birds, on a daily basis to MPP.
(viii) It is usual for MPP to take the birds from the grower at around days 36, 43 and 55 of the cycle. MPP on these occasions (i.e. days 36 and 43) decide the number of birds they will take and the sex of the birds.
(ix) When MPP takes delivery of birds it arranges to provide "catchers" whom the grower pays
(x) The grower is paid for the weight of the live birds delivered to the factory: he is not paid for birds classified by the Department of Agriculture Veterinary Officer " as dead or useless".
(xi) The offal from the birds is, with the grower's permission, kept by MPP and subsequently processed, rendered and sold by MPP to 3 of the millers who supply meal to MPP's growers.

16. The growers are not paid for the offal.

(xii) In terms of paperwork, the grower receives the following from MPP.
(a) "a day old" invoice recording sex, the number and price of the day olds re
ceived by the grower; 2% of the day olds are given "free". This in
voice is received at or about the time of delivery of the load but does
not have not be paid at that time.
(b) an invoice from MPP in respect of meal ordered through MPP: again this invoice is not required to be discharged at the time of its receipt.
(c) a purchase note from MPP in respect of each load of birds taken by MPP which lists the number and weight of the live birds and the number and weight of the useless or dead birds. It also recites the price to be paid by MPP.
(d) approximately 7 weeks after the end of the 8 week growing cycle, the grower gets his cheque together with a settlement statement which lists
(i) the value of each load in the batch (as per the purchase
note)
(ii) the price of the day olds
(iii) the price of meal purchased
age of the growers house
(xiii) the cost of vaccination against disease is borne by the grower. The cost of any post mortems is borne by MPP.

17. The foregoing as I have noted represent the conditions applicable at the date of these proceedings. It is worthwhile recounting some of the conditions, which, though relevant to the proceedings, had ceased to apply to the contractual relationship at the date of the proceedings:-

(i) In February, 1991 MPP introduced a forklift charge and a litter
charge to coincide with the purchase by them of forklifts whereby they collected live birds in plastic modules and loaded them onto a flat trailer for delivery to their plant. The litter charge was for litter stuck to the module; the forklift charge was ostensibly to pay for the capital investment in, and maintenance of, the forklifts. These charges amounted to £13 per 1000 birds. The charges were subsumed by the new flesh price introduced in November, 1993.
(ii) In January and November, 1992, 2 further charges were introduced each £10 per 1000 birds; the first was intended by MPP as a grower contribution to the modernisation of MPP's plant; the second, to compensate for the ills of the November, 1992 "sterling crisis". The charges were built into the November, 1993 flesh price.

18. The proceedings were instituted on 13th May, 1994. They followed a period of two years in which the Plaintiff growers were unhappy at the way MPP were conducting their business with the growers. They formed an association and elected Mr. Blemings as Chairman and Mr. Quigley as Secretary. A series of meetings were held between MPP officers and members of the growers' association. The growers complaints aired at these meetings can be summarised thus:-


(a) Growers should be allowed purchase their own meal directly from the millers.
(b) All meal should be tested for its metabolising content.
fied.
(d) The delayed cheque payment for flesh was unwarranted.
(e) The flesh price offered to growers was unfair.
(f) Millers were not dealing satisfactorily with growers complaints.
(g) The variation in gross margins was due to poor quality control over feed.

19. On 10th November, 1993 MPP absorbed all the deductions (save the £5/£25 per 1000 birds) into a new flesh price of £0.33 per lb. On 11th March, 1994 MPP offered to introduce a new flesh price of 27.89p per lb. and a new meal price of £210 per tonne; the meal price had been £266 per tonne and the flesh price

33p per lb. The charges proposed did not come into effect probably because, in a letter dated 14th March 1994, the Plaintiffs Solicitors labelled the offer as:

"This unilateral action on the part of the company is clear evidence of the unfair trading conditions imposed on the growers and is clearly in breach of the Competition Act, 1991."

20. On 9th May 19994 Mr. Barry McEntee wrote to each of the growers in which he recounted proposals made by MPP to the association as follows:-

(i) a quality monitoring programme for meal
(ii) any results of an analysis of meal to be provided to the relevant grower
(iii) Growers can visit mills and request a change from a miller if they wish.
(iv) MPP proposed to reduce the price of feed along with a pro rata reduction in the price of flesh
(v) MPP proposed to abolish the £5/£25 deduction and replace it by a single deduction of £8 per 1000 birds.

21. His letter assured growers that


"any birds classified as dead and useless are those that are so graded by Department of agriculture officials only."

22. On 1st November, 1995, MPP offered its growers new terms and conditions. Discussion followed the publication of these terms and as a result MPP's Barry McEntee wrote to growers on 24th November, 1995 enclosing "A" and "B" terms and conditions to be effective from 8th December, 1995. Under the A Conditions the growers would purchase their meal through MPP but at prices generally in line with open market prices. Under the B Conditions, a grower would be free to purchase his own meal, but would be responsible for the disposal of his own bird offal. Growers opting for the A conditions were to get 26.438p per lb. and those opting for the B conditions 25.438p per lb. Both sets of draft conditions had detailed terms dealing with quality assurance. On 15th December 1995, in these proceedings an undertaking was given by MPP not to introduce the proposed terms pending the determination of this action. On that date (the 15th December, 1995) the flesh price was 33p per lb. MPP altered the price subsequently on 2 occasions -

31st January, 1996 and 1st April, 1996. The current price is 27P per lb.




(6) UNFAIR PRICING

23. In aid of the argument that the prices offered by MPP were and are unfair prices, the Plaintiffs adduced evidence of -


(a) the results of a questionnaire prepared by Mr. Quigley and answered on behalf of growers of 6 other processors
(b) the price offered for chicken flesh by Cootehill Co-operative Society.
(c) the market price of meal of the four designated MPP millers compared with the price MPP sold that meal to the Plaintiffs.
(d) generally declining gross margins between 1991 and 1996.
(e) the price of day olds charged by different processors.
(v)
(a) THE QUESTIONNAIRE

24. The questionnaire was submitted by Mr. Quigley to Mr. Ned Walsh of the poultry section of the Irish Farmers Association. He, according to Mr. Quigley, obtained the information necessary to complete the questionnaire from 5 Irish groups of growers whom the Defendant MPP suggested in evidence grew for Cartons, Kantoher, Western Brands, Castlemahon and Cappoquin. Further questionnaires were completed for MPP growers (by Mr. Quigley) and a Scottish grower. All of the questionnaires related to the month of January, 1996. If one allows that any evidential weight should attach to the questionnaires filled out by Mr. Walsh, the conclusions to be drawn from the answers of the growers do not clearly suggest a proposition that MPP is paying a price which is less than the economic value of the chicken flesh or that other processors are, pound for pound, paying a greater price than MPP. Indeed, an analysis of the answers shows that there are so many variables applicable to each processor and its growers that no real price comparison is possible.


(b) THE COOTEHILL PRICE

25. Jack Scott gave evidence that Cootehill Co-operative Society has a processing plant with a capacity for 35,000 to 40,000 birds per week. There are 50 employees in a modern plant. 14 persons grow for the co-operative, of whom 13 are members, holding shares in the co-operative. Mr. Scott indicated that he was a director of the co-operative from the outset. He produced a schedule of prices paid by him for meal between 1991 and 1996 for use in his Cootehill production. He also produced a schedule of the prices paid by Cootehill for its chicken flesh. Cootehill growers were able to purchase meal on the open market at all material times. Mr. Scott allowed that the price for meal from Kavanaghs and Paul and Vincent, as shown in his Schedule, included a discount which was variable. The working committee of Cootehill comprised 8 persons (including Mr. Scott) and fixed the flesh price payable to growers: as Mr. Scott said:


"we pay ourselves what we call a reasonable price for chicken that the market will carry and to keep our growers reasonably happy"

26. Because Mr. Scott was a member of the co-operative and because its members were in effect deciding what they should pay to themselves as growers for chicken flesh, Mr. Quigley and the other Plaintiffs suggested that by subtracting 1p from the flesh price paid by Cootehill, the price would represent an "arms length" or market price. I set out hereunder the contents of the Schedule produced by Mr. Scott which are relevant to the matters in issue in this case:


MPP PRICE COOTEHILL PRICE
1991 33.902 pence/lb. 30.207 pence/lb
29.572

1992 33.902 29.572
28.484

1993 33.00 28.484
29.391

1994 33.00 29.391
28.484

1995 33.00 28.484

1996 33.000 28.484
26.438 29.845
27.000
27.000

27. The Plaintiffs suggest that in assessing what is a fair price, Cootehill is a valid comparison, and, that the price paid by MPP should be compared to it, after MPP's margin on the meal and the other deductions are subtracted from the price. Mr. Magee an accountant who gave evidence for the Plaintiffs assessed the difference between the price charged to the Plaintiffs for meal and the cost to MPP of that meal between 1991 and 1996. He also assessed the value of the deductions made by MPP in that same period. He added these two sums together and then subtracted the flesh price differences between the actual MPP price and the Cootehill (minus 1p) price. The figure emerging from this calculation is a figure of £2,551,681 for the period from 1st February, 1991 (prior to the coming into force of the 1991 Act) to date: this is part of the Plaintiffs' claim for damages in these proceedings..


(c) THE PRICE OF MEAL

28. Mr. Magee compared the market price of meal, the price charged by the millers to MPP and the price charged by MPP to the Plaintiff growers. This exercise was partly completed through an analysis of an MPP ledger called the Red Meal Book which detailed the amounts charged to growers for meal and the cost of that meal to MPP. I return to this matter later in this Judgment.



(d) GROSS MARGINS

29. The evidence clearly established - and it was commoncase - that the average grower margins had declined from 1992 through 1996. What was not agreed were the reasons for such a decline.


30. The growers margin (i.e. gross margin over feed and chicks per 1000 birds) for the years 1992 to 1996 was calculated by each of the parties as follows:-


MPP GROWERS
1992 £221.44 £222.73
1993 £210.71 £212.04
1994 £194.58 £193.54
1995 £197.62 £190.14
1996 £165.67 £156.73

31. The Plaintiffs suggest that the reasons for the decline in margins are due to the unfair pricing system of MPP, the difference in quality between the meal of different millers, increased mortality rates, disease rates and poor quality day olds. MPP, for their part, suggest that looking at average margins is misleading and that the mean or average is only a central tendency, and that one should observe what is happening with certain growers who have actually increased their margins in the same period. MPP's analysis suggest there is no such thing as a "representative" grower with declining margins. They suggest that their pricing system can be rationalized on the basis of market trends and that shrinking margins (where they occur) reflects a declining product market and bad management on the growers' part.


(e) PRICE OF DAY OLD CHICKS .

32. The answers in the questionnaires furnished by Mr Walsh to

33. Mr. Quigley show widely different approaches to the provision of day old

chicks. Kantoher apparently charge nothing; Cappoquin £15 per 1000; MPP

34. £205 per 1000; Cartons £198 per 1000 with Western Brands topping the league

at £235 per 1000.
(7) MEAL

35. Both the Plaintiff growers and MPP saw meal quality as critical. The growers saw high quality meal as giving them a good food conversion ratio ("FCR") and MPP saw high quality meal as ensuring a high quality product. The Plaintiffs' witnesses saw cost advantages and quality control advantages to them in purchasing meal direct from growers of their choice. While much evidence was adduced as to the FCR of the Plaintiff growers (and the FCRs of other growers as relayed by

36. Mr. Walsh) the Plaintiff did not establish any causal link between any of the

4 designated millers and a poor FCR. The evidence of Dr. McIlmoyle and

37. Mr. Wilson, both nutritionists called by MPP, was that feed conversion was influenced by many factors other than the quality of the feed: they identified the following factors: the sex of the bird, the age at which the bird is killed, the time of year, the temperature, ammonia levels, mortality, management practices and the disease status of the flock. That FCR was affected by such a range of factors was something with which Mr. Bole, a nutritionist, with David Patton Limited (and called by the Plaintiffs) agreed. Mr. Wilson outlined recent developments in the industry designed to ensure "biosecurity" and "traceability". He said that supermarkets are now dictating what goes into chicken feed and are requiring the processors to show due diligence in their compliance with the supermarkets' requirements. Mrs. O'Driscoll said that, in the context of traceability, it would be "an administrative nightmare" if growers could purchase meal independently of MPP and she feared they would not keep records so as to meet the requirements of traceability. Her evidence was that at present MPP know what meal is sent to every grower and accordingly MPP can trace from the consumer product back to the meal the particular bird was fed on. She said:


"We supply a quality product. You have to at the end of the day. The input into feeding the bird is meal. You have to be able to guarantee quality due diligence right across the whole train".

38. She acknowledged that where the bird supplied was below standard the liability would fall on MPP ultimately.


39. Supporting Mrs. O'Driscoll's evidence as to traceability was Victor Truesdale, Sales Director, of Thompsons, a firm of millers, who said:


"With the demands of consumer and the demands of the retail supermarket chains, they expect what we call traceability of product right through the system from purchase of raw material right through to the flesh of the chicken ...."

40. Mr. Quigley, on the other hand, was confident that quality could be assured in circumstances where growers purchased directly from the millers.


41. Mrs. Traynor, Mr. Scott, Mr. McKenna and Mr. Quigley all recounted difficulties they had with the MPP designated millers and they were of the view that if they had a direct contractional relationship the millers would have been more responsive to their difficulties, and that they could control quality in conjunction with MPP. As to cost, Mr. Quigley and the other Plaintiff growers believed that if they were free to purchase their own meal either collectively or individually as growers, they could improve their gross margins. Mr. Magee, the Plaintiffs' accountant, gave evidence that having examined the Books of MPP he could show that between December, 1991 and December 1995 the price charged by MPP for meal was in the region of £266 per tonne whereas the cost per tonne to MPP was in the region of £210 during the same period. Mrs. O'Driscoll, on behalf of MPP gave evidence that MPP did not make any profit on the meal and that the meal when charged at £266 per tonne resulted in the flesh price being "inflated" to 33p per lb. and that "one was compensated for in the other".


42. Mrs. O'Driscoll acknowledged that in the past Manor Mills gave a rebate of some £6 pr tonne to them which was only passed on to the growers after December 1995. It was commoncase that the price paid by MPP for its meal was significantly lower than the list prices of the millers.


43. On account of its bulk purchasing, Mr. Bole of Pattons believed that for similar volumes and similar credit terms Pattons would supply the growers at the same prices as they, Pattons, supplied MPP (Pattons supplied 20% of MPP's meal requirements).


44. As I have already indicated MPP adduced evidence as to the importance of the quality of meal to any processor. Mrs. O'Driscoll stated that MPP "need to be able to guarantee that quality".


45. All processors in the Republic of Ireland (save Cootehill) require their growers to purchase their meal through them. This started in the 1960s - and in MPP's case became a term of the agreements with growers in 1976. A similar practice exists in the United Kingdom.


(8) DEAD AND USELESS BIRDS

46. The Plaintiff growers are not paid for birds unless the birds are alive when 'admitted' to the processing plant. They can die en route to the plant and, indeed, while awaiting processing in the yard adjoining the plant. Apart from dead birds, the growers are not paid for birds condemned as "useless" by the Department of Agriculture. As already noted, MPP's managing director, Barry McEntee, in a letter dated 9th May, 1994 addressed to the growers stated:

"Any birds classified as dead and useless are those that are so graded by Department of Agriculture Officials only." (his emphasis)

47. When a load of birds is taken from a grower by MPP, the grower receives a purchase note which details among other things the number of dead and useless birds in the load together with their weight. The production procedures manual for MPP adopted by MPP on 17th December, 1992 provides under the heading Dead and useless as follows


"All matters relating to the state of a load of birds must be recorded such detail as dead or animal Vet's rejects, useless, green legs general condition of bird, died in crate etc., must be recorded. This form REV2 must be completed by the Ramp Manager and forwarded to the Purchasing Officer. Vets rejects and useless birds must be removed from the line three times per day .....The useless birds should be removed to the Boning Hall Chill for processing. Vets rejects should be removed to the offal plant."

48. Department of Agriculture condemnations for the months of May to August 1994 (both months inclusive) showed condemnations for growers that were at variance with the purchase notes relative to the same loads. Equally, forms REV 2 showed dead and useless figures that did not coincide with those of the Department for the same period. The REV 2 form figures (filled in by MPP employees) for 'VB' (vet's bin) 'GL' (green leg) and 'useless' coincided with the "dead and useless" figure on the purchase notes. By way of example, in Mr. Quigley's case. on 22nd July, 1994,

38 birds were shown as "VB" and 7 as "GL" and "30" as "useless" making a total of 75. His purchase note showed 75 as useless but the Departmental record shows only 38 as condemned. Mr. John McGlone said that the Department of Agriculture officials "never left the line" since late 1993, and that the only circumstance in which an employee would take a bird off the line was if the veterinary officer was not there.

49. Mrs. O'Driscoll, in her evidence, was of the view that what Barry McEntee said in his letter to growers about condemnations was incorrect and that there are occasions where MPP employees will still remove birds "but the Department will sign and authorize those..." While I had before me REV 2 forms for different periods of time, together with the relevant purchase notes and Departmental condemnations for July 1994, I did not have established in evidence any document signed by a departmental official authorizing the condemnation of birds as 'useless' which had been removed from the line by MPP employees. Nor did I have before me any amendment to page 8 of the production procedures manual 1992. I did however have evidence of an MPP meeting, held in December 1994 , to discuss the need to reconcile the Departmental condemnations and MPP's own figures for dead and useless.


(9) THE ECONOMIC ISSUES

50. David Jacobson is a senior lecturer in economics at Dublin City University. He holds the degree of Doctor of Philosophy from the University of Dublin and is the author of a number of academic articles. His area of speciality is industrial economics and organization. Dr. John Fingleton is an economist and lecturer in the University of Dublin. He has co-authored a text on competition policy and has written a number of articles on competition matters.


51. Both economists gave evidence as to the relevant product market and the relevant geographic market and whether, in such market, MPP is in a dominant position and if it is, whether its conduct constitutes an abuse of dominance. Both Dr. Jacobson (for the Plaintiff growers) and Dr. Fingleton (for MPP) were agreed on the relevant product market: it was the market for the provision of a broiler growing service. Where the economists were in disagreement was as to the relevant geographic market and MPP's role in such a market. Dr. Jacobson acknowledged that the relevant product market was an intermediate one and that broiler growing is in fact an input into the processor's production of final product - namely, the processed chicken, or portions thereof, sold to retailers. While in many respects that intermediate market will be affected by what happens in the "downstream" market where MPP sells its chicken product, and is, therefore, not entirely independent of that market, nonetheless the extent of the geographic market for broiler growing services does not in any way depend on the geographic market for chicken flesh. Dr. Jacobson adverted to the existence of barriers to entry to the market for broiler growing services, being the processors control over who will supply the services; and also barriers to exit being evidenced, he said, by the lack of mobility of growers between processors. He drew attention to the high sunk costs, being the expenditure on chicken houses and equipment. Dr. Jacobson expressed the opinion that the relevant geographic market was best determined by observing the clustering of growers in relation to processors. Such an empirical analysis, which showed that MPP's growers were, in general, located no more than 15 miles from MPP pointed, he said, to the fact that the spatial range of the market was extremely limited. Given the absence of mobility over time of growers from one processor to another (he took account of a single movement of MPP growers to Cartons in the mid 1980s, the single movement of oriel growers to MPP in 1995, and the erection of new houses by new growers over the years). Dr. Jacobson was of opinion that the relevant geographic market was located in County Monaghan within a 15 mile radius of MPP's processing plant. He did not think that the presence of a few isolated growers outside that range was relevant to his conclusion on the geographic market.


52. Having formed a view as to the geographic market, Dr. Jacobson advanced reasons for the existence of such a spatially limited market: the tight agglomeration of growers around MPP made the organization and monitoring of growers easier and less expensive; the proximity to the plant reduced the extent of chicken mortality where birds were transported in adverse weather conditions; and, finally, transport costs were a relevant factor in the observed clustering. While Dr. Fingleton, as I have stated, agreed on the relevant product market, he disagreed with Dr. Jacobson as to what was the relevant geographic market for the product. In his opinion, the geographic market was the island of Ireland. As Dr. Fingleton noted, the geographic market referred to the geographic region in which competition occurred. He observed that competition occurred in the downstream market for chicken flesh and that ultimately that competition will affect conditions of competition in the upstream market for the provision of broiler services. He believed that because price competition (described by Mrs. O'Driscoll as "cut throat") necessarily impacted on the upstream market, growers for different processors, throughout Ireland, were indirectly in competition with one another in the provision of their broiler growing service. Dr. Fingleton did not believe transport costs limit the geographic market: he was of the view that a grower wishing to leave MPP has several alternatives: he could switch to another processor in the local area, he could switch to a processor further away or he could exit the market.


53. Dr. Jacobson observed that the position of MPP in the relevant product market was, in substance, that of a monopsonist. A Monopsony, he said, exists where a firm is the sole buyer of a good or service. It is the opposite of a monopoly. He noted that George T Sigler put it ( in the Theory of Price, McMillon 1996) thus:-


"The firm which is the only buyer of a productive service (a monopsonist) has the same power to control price in buying that a monopolist has in selling".

54. The observable barriers to entry and exit from the market, and the general lack of mobility of growers, provides MPP with potential to exploit its growers according to Dr. Jacobson. In particular, he said, MPP has the capacity to use its monopsony power to impose unfair trading conditions and prices unilaterally. He gave as examples of a condition imposed "contrary to the interests of the growers" the prevention of growers from negotiating the purchase of meal directly from the millers; further, he said, as a monopsony buyer, MPP has used its power to determine the broiler growers margins unilaterally. The use of such power in such a manner amounts to an abuse of a dominant position by MPP. Professor Rodney Thom, the Jean Monnet Professor of Economics at University College Dublin, with a special expertise in econometrics, looked at the relationship between price structure and returns in the production of chicken meat. His main conclusions were that market prices for feed and final output are independent from the relationship between growers and processors; that causation runs from final market prices to flesh prices paid by processors, and, that recent trends suggested to him a market characterised by increased competition and declining output prices, in which it was, he said, untenable to suggest that the MPP could guarantee "a fair" price or return to growers. Professor Thom (see Table 1 below) looked at the pre December 1995 price structure (feed: £266 per tonne; chicks £19 per 100; flesh £0.33 per lb.) and the December proposal of MPP of £20.50 per 100 chicks, £195 per tonne feed and £0.27038 per lb. for flesh. He was able to establish that the proposed price structure, if implemented, would have left the return to growers virtually unaffected


Table 1. Price Schedules

(9 week cycle, FCR = 1.96, crops per year = 5.00, ave. wt. = 4.46 lb)


Schedule 1.

Schedule 2
Feed price( £/tonne)

266.00

195.00
Chick Price (£/00)

19.00

20.50
Flesh Price (p/lb.)

33.00

27.04





Sales

493,272.38

40,452.44
Feed Costs

35,381.65

25,937.67
Chick Costs

6,650.00

7,175.00





Return (£/1000b)

227.66

227.63
Deduction: £5/000

222.66

222,.63





Net Income (year)

14,468.12

14,426.52






55. As to the suggestion that preventing growers from negotiating the purchase of meal directly from the millers was unfair and anti-competitive, Dr. Fingleton was of the view such conduct was not abusive, not anti-consumer and could, in any event, be objectively justified.


(10) THE FINANCIAL POSITION OF MPP

56. Desmond Murnane, a chartered accountant, gave evidence on behalf of the Plaintiff growers. He had been furnished with the audited accounts of MPP for the years ending 31st December, 1991 to 1994, MPP's draft accounts for the year ending

31st December, 1995 and management accounts for the period 1st January, 1994 to 31st May, 1996. He also looked at other financial information provided by MPP and accounts of related companies to MPP. The picture he found, on his analysis, was of a company, which since 1991, had declined in profitability from a profit after tax in 1991 of £1,133,000 to a loss after tax of £349,000 for the year to 31st December, 1995. The losses in that last year were contributed to by increases in depreciation and bank interest of £318,000. The bank borrowings as at 31st May 1996 stood at £2.789 million and resulted entirely from the purchase by Phaebour Services Limited of 30% of the shares in MPP. That purchase was assisted by a loan raised by MPP from its bankers. Though lent to Phaebour no interest on the loan has been paid to MPP or is shown as due in the accounts of MPP. MPP contend that their bankers are unwilling to advance to them any further monies and that were the Plaintiffs to succeed in their claim they would as a company be forced into liquidation.

(11) THE LAW

(a) General

57. The long title to the Competition Act, 1991 ("the Act") states:-


"an Act to prohibit, by analogy with Articles 85 and 86 of the Treaty establishing the European Economic Community, and in the interests of the common good, the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition and the abuse of dominant positions in trade in the State, to establish a competition authority to amend the Mergers Takeovers and Monopolies (Control) Act 1978 and to provide for other matters connected with the matters aforesaid."

as Keane J. pointed out in Deane and Others -v- VHI Board (22nd April, 1993, unreported) at p. 105.

"The long title of the Act indicates that it has been enacted 'by analogy with Articles 85 and 86 of the Treaty ..... The analogy is necessarily incomplete since one of the principle objectives of the Treaty (some would say the paramount objective) is the establishment of a single integrated market in the community whereas such a market already exists in the State".

Section 4(1) of the Act provides as follows:-
"Subject to the provisions of this Section all agreements between undertakings decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which have as their object or effect the prevention restriction or distortion of competition in trade in any goods or services in the State or in any part of the State are prohibited and void including in particular, without prejudice to the generality of this subsection, those which:-
(a) directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling prices or any other trading conditions.
(b) limit or control production, markets, technical development or investment.
(c) share markets or sources of supply.
(d) apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage.
(e) make the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by other parties of supplementary obligations which by their nature or according to commercial usage have no connection with the subject of such contracts"

58. The balance of Section 4 contains provisions relating to the licensing or certification of agreements decisions and concerted practices by the competition authority established under the Act


Section 5 of the Act provides:
"(1) any abuse by one or more undertaking of a dominant position in trade for any goods or services in the State or in a substantial part of the State is prohibited.
(2) Without prejudice to the generality of subsection (1) such abuse may, in particular, consist in
(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions.
(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers.
(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage.
(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to the acceptance by other parties of supplementary obligations which by their nature or according to commercial usage have no connection with the subject of such contracts".

59. While it may be said that Article 85(1) closely mirrors Section 4(1) of the Act, it is not identical in wording. Article 85(1) contains the additional phrase:"Which may effect trade ...." in qualifying the prohibited conduct, whereas, the Section 4(1) conduct is not so qualified - but limits or qualifies the competition which is sought to be protected as "competition in trade". Equally, Article 86 is similar in terms but not identical to Section 5(1) and (2) of the Act. In

Article 86 , the abusive conduct is prohibited only "insofar as it may affect trade ...", whereas, Section 5(1) prohibits abuses of a dominant position "in trade for any goods or services". Apart from the foregoing, Article 85 , of course, concerns itself with trade "between" member States and competition "within the common market" whereas Section 4 is concerned with competition in trade "in the State or any part of it". Article 86 refers to the "common market" and conduct which may affect trade "between member States" whereas Section 5 refers to conduct occurring in the "State or in an substantial part of the State".

60. The rules on competition, contained in Articles 85 to 94 of the Treaty of Rome (as amended), are interpreted having regard to the general objectives of the Treaty; additionally, in looking at the Rules on Competition other provisions of the Treaty may be relevant (for example the Article 36 restriction on imports or exports grounded on public policy). In Masterfoods Ltd. -v- HB Ice Cream Limited 1993 ILRM 145 Keane J. warned that ( at p. 184 ) Article 85 "is not to be considered in isolation from other provisions of the Treaty". Also the provisions of Articles 85 to 94 may be influenced by Community policies in other areas (such as patent and know how licensing). As Keane J. noted in Deane -v- VHI , supra, at p.107 the 1991 Act is an autonomous Act of the Oireachtas and not one implementing a directive of the European Union. It has its own machinery for implementing its rules on completion which are quite different to those of the Treaty. In applying the jurisprudence of the European Courts of Justice, the Court of First instance and the Commission, to Sections 4 and 5 of the 1991 Act, there is no doubt that decision of those bodies should have very strong persuasive force - however it should be borne in mind that such decisions are based upon competition rules which are, textually and contextually, different to the 1991 rules and which often are decisions influenced or affected either by policy considerations, objectives or Articles of the Treaty which do not necessarily underpin the 1991 Act.


(b) SECTION 4 OF THE COMPETITION ACT, 1991

(i) The Plaintiff growers say that each of their agreements with MPP offends Section 4 of the Act in the following respects:-
(a) deductions have been made to the price of chicken flesh paid to them in a unilateral fashion.
(b) certain growers have been paid more for their chicken flesh than others by MPP.
(c) MPP requires growers to purchase their meal through MPP at a price determined by MPP.

61. The Plaintiff growers also contend that there is a concerted practice, or arrangement, between MPP and the millers who supply MPP with the object or effect of restricting competition in chicken feed. In summary, the Plaintiffs say that MPP has restricted competition by imposing unfair purchase prices (contrary to Section 4(1)(a) of the Act on the growers, by price discriminating between growers (contrary to S.4(1)(d) of the Act and by restricting their ability to purchase meal independently (contrary to S.4(1)(e) of the Act). The Plaintiffs urged that in considering whether there was an infringement of Section 4 I should adopt the approach of the Court in Societe Technique Miniere -v- Maschinenbau Ulm GmbH 1966 ECR 235 , namely, I should first look at the object of the agreement or concerted practice; if the object does not by its nature restrict competition I should next consider the effect of the agreement or practice on competition taking into account the whole economic context in which the agreement operates. The Plaintiffs say that in judging the effect of the agreement, regard should be had to the competition that would occur in the absence of the practice or agreement in dispute; that the effect on competition must be "appreciable" and, in that context, it is relevant for the Court to look at the market share of the relevant parties in the relevant market whether the agreement stands in isolation or is part of a network of agreements. The Plaintiffs submit that if the Court finds that the object of an agreement or practice is to restrict competition, the Court does not have to consider its effect on competition. They submit that this is the approach adopted by Keane J. in Masterfoods Limited -v- HB Ice Cream Limited 1993 ILRM 145 in relation to Article 85 of the Treaty and it is an equally appropriate way in which to look at Section 4 of the 1991 Act. The Plaintiffs say that MPP's systematic deductions from growers' margins together with the gradual, but consistent decline, of those margins points to an agreement or practice which necessarily has as its object or effect the restriction of competition in that it, directly or indirectly, imposes on the growers unfair purchasing prices for chicken flesh. Equally, they submit that the agreement or practice whereby they are required to purchase their meal through MPP has the object or effect of restricting competition and is a contractual term which has no real connection with the subject matter of their contracts, namely, the provision of a broiler growing service. Finally, in relation to

Section 4 , the Plaintiffs say that the different treatment of some growers (through £5/£25 deduction and the flesh price incentive for new growers) also has the object or effect of restricting competition by applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions.

62. The Plaintiffs place strong reliance on the decision of the European Court of Justice in Co-operative Stemsel en Kleurselfabrick -v- Commission 1982 1 CMLR 227 where the Court held that the rules of a production co-operative which required its members to obtain from it all their supplies of certain substances (rennet of animal origin and colouring agents for cheese) constituted an infringement of Article 85(1) of the Treaty.


63. Two decisions in relation to Article 85(1) are worth recording: they are the decisions of the European Court of Justice in Metro (No 1) 1977 ECR 1875 , and in Metro (No 2) 1980 ECR 3021 , where the European Court decided that certain 'restrictions' did not amount to restrictions on competition within the meaning of Article 85(1) if they could be " objectively justified " by certain policy considerations. In each case, SABA refused to supply its electrical products to Metro Cash and Carry outlets. Metro alleged that the refusal to supply, and a maintained system of high prices, offended Article 85(1) . While SABA undoubtedly restricted competition, the Court decided not to apply Article 85(1) to a system based on qualitative technical criteria applied by a supplier of technical goods. The Court in deciding that the restriction was justified under Article 85(1) balanced the price rigidity of such a system against the possible improved competition through the maintenance of standards of service. The editor of Bellamy and Child's Common Market Law of Competition , 4th Edition , comments on Metro, at para. 2-083 :


"The result of Metro is to establish a further category of agreements which do not fall within Article 85(1) namely these in which the restrictions are objectively justified because they seek other ends accepted as desirable or reasonable." (emphasis added)

(c) SECTION 5 OF THE COMPETITION ACT, 1991

64. The Plaintiffs say that the 'unfair' purchase prices offered by MPP for chicken flesh, the restriction on the purchase of meal other than through MPP, and the price discrimination of MPP, are all features of what they submit is abusive conduct within Section 5 of the Act. They contend that the Court in assessing such conduct should follow the approach of the European Court which approach is, first, to identify the relevant product market, then the relevant geographic market and having established the market consider whether the undertaking is in a dominant position in that market and if so, whether it has abused that position. This was the approach adopted by Keane J. in Masterfoods Limited -v- HB Ice Cream Limited 1993 ILRM, with which I respectfully agree. There was no dispute between the parties as to the relevant product market: it was the market for the provision of a broiler growing service. There was however disagreement on the relevant geographic market. The "dominant position" to which Section 5 refers is one defined by reference to a good or service and by reference to a geographic area of the State. The geographic market is an area in which the conditions of competition applying to the product are the same for all traders. In United Brands Company and United Brands Continental BV -v- Commission 1978 ICMLR 429 the European Court said:


"The opportunities for competition under Article 86 of the Treaty must be considered having regard to the particular features of the product in question and with reference to a clearly defined geographic area in which it is marketed and where the conditions of competition are sufficiently homogeneous for the effect of the economic power of the undertaking concerned to be evaluated."

65. The Plaintiffs argue, in reliance on Dr. Jacobson's evidence, that the relevant geographic area is an area within a 15 mile radius of MPP's processing plant whereas the Defendant argues that the geographic area which falls to be considered is the island of Ireland.


66. Both parties accepted as applicable to Section 5 definitions of "dominance" and "abuse of dominance" found in Article 86 cases. In Hoffman - La Roche -v- Commission of EC 1979 3 CMLR 211 , the Court defined 'dominance' as:-


"a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extend independently of its competitors, its customers and ultimately of the consumers".

Again in Hoffman-La Roche, Supra , 'abuse of dominance' was considered:-

"The concept of abuse is an objective concept relating to the behaviour of an undertaking in a dominant position which is such as to influence the structure of a market where as a result of the very presence of the undertaking in question the degree of competition is weakened and which through recourse to methods different from those which condition normal competition in products or services on the basis of the transactions of commercial operators has the effect of hindering the maintenance of the degree of competition still existing in the market or the growth of that competition".

67. In considering allegedly "abusive conduct" the European Court of Justice has been prepared to look at the conduct in question for the purpose of assessing whether it can be objectively justified and whether the conduct can be said to amount to what is regarded as normal competitive practices. There are a number of decisions of the Court of Justice which endorse this approach: among them Michelin -v- Commission 1985 1 CMLR 282 and Tetra-Pak Rausing SA -v- Commission. 1991 4CMLR 334 . These authorities are quoted with approval by Keane J. in Masterfoods Limited, supra , and it suffices here to refer to a passage from the judgment of the Court in Michelin, supra ,:


"Article 86 covers practices which are likely to affect the structure of a market where as a direct result of the presence of the undertaking in question competition has already been weakened and which through recourse to methods different from those governing normal competition in products or services based on traders' performance, have the effect of hindering the maintenance or development of the level of competition still existing in the market."

68. As Advocate General Krischner observed in Tetra-Pak, supra


"The EEC Treaty does not require the undertaking in a dominant position to act in a way which makes no economic sense and is against its legitimate interest ...The undertaking in a dominant position may act in a profit oriented way ..... but in so doing it may employ only such methods as are necessary to pursue those legitimate aims. In particular it may not act in a away which forseeably will limit competition more than necessary ". (emphasis added ).

69. The Plaintiffs complaint of infringement of Section 5 is that unfair purchasing prices are "imposed" by MPP for their chicken flesh. They say the flesh price is fixed unfairly low and is designed to achieve and has achieved for MPP 'supernormal' profits. A number of cases before the European Court have dealt with the issue of alleged unfair selling prices. The evidential burden applied in these cases appears to me to be relevant to the present case.


In United Brands, supra , the Court held that charging a price which is excessive because it has no reasonable relation to the economic value of the product supplied may be an abuse of a dominant position within Article 86(a) the Court held that:-

"this excess could inter alia be determined objectively if it were possible for it to be calculated by making a comparison between the selling price of the product in question and its cost of production which would disclose the amount of the profit margin."

In Bodson -v- Pompes Funbres Des Regions Liberes (1988 ECR 2479) at issue (inter alia) was whether unfair prices were charged for burials by the subsidiances of an undertaking. The Court held that:
"it must be possible to make a comparison between the prices charged by the group of undertakings which held concessions and prices charged elsewhere. Such a comparison could provide a basis for assessing whether or not the prices charged by the concession holders are fair" .

70. The Plaintiff growers also contend that MPP is not only a monoponist - but a price discriminating monoponist, in that it has, as noted above, applied its deductions and flesh prices in a discriminatory fashion in breach of Section 5(2)(c) of the 1991 Act. It is argued that the same deductions and prices should have been applied to all and that the failure to do so has disadvantaged some of the growers. Bellamy and Childs, supra (at para. 9.055) observing on the equivalent provision in Article 86 say:-


"In broad terms price discrimination consists of not treating like cases alike. in other words, different prices are not discriminatory unless there is no objective justification for the difference."

71. The final complaint of the Plaintiffs relates to Section 5(2)(d) of the 1991 Act. It is contended that the growers obligation under their agreements with MPP to purchase their meal from MPP is the imposition fo a supplementary obligation which by its nature and according to commercial usage has not any connection with the broiler growing service agreement. The Plaintiffs rely on Hilti -v Commission 1992 4CMLR 16 . Hilti manufactured and supplied power driven nail guns. It occupied a dominant position in the supply of these guns. It also supplied cartridge strips and nails with the guns. It required purchasers of the guns to purchase its nails. The Court of First Instance held that its conduct was abusive. Hilti had argued that safety considerations justified it in insisting on the purchase of its nails with its gun. Technical reports on nails manufactured by the complainants (against Hilti) established defects in those nails. The Court held that Hilti could not justify the tying provision on product liability grounds where it could invoke national laws concerning product liability to protect its position. In Tetra-Pak, 14th November, 1996, (unreported) , the ECJ again considered a tying clause. Tetra- Pak's customers were contractually obliged inter alia to purchase from Tetra Pack all their requirements of carton packaging material used in Tetra-Paks carton filling machines. The Court did not accept that such a tie was justified on the grounds that it eliminated the difficult question of apportioning responsibility for any defect in the system to the supplier of the machine and the supplier of the packaging material and, also, that it was necessary to safeguard public health because of the dangers inherent in storing milk at ambient temperatures. The ECJ at para 36 approving of the decision of the Court of First Instance noted that that Court had held


"that it was not for Tetra-Pak to impose certain measures on its own initiative on the basis of technical considerations or considerations relating to product liability, protection of public health and protection of its reputation". (emphasis added)

CONCLUSIONS

[A] SECTION 5 OF THE COMPETITION ACT 1991

(i) DOMINANT POSITION

72. I shall deal first with the issues which arise in relation to section 5 . As I indicated earlier there was no dispute between the parties as to the relevant product market: it was the market for the provision of a broiler growing service. The dispute between the parties was as to where the competition in that market took place.

73. Dr Jacobson suggested that the geographic market was determined by observing the physical location of growers in relation to processors. He found that the clustering of MPPs growers in a 15 mile radius around the processing plant combined with a history of lack of mobility of these growers from MPP to any other processor defined the geographic market as one located in County Monaghan. Dr Fingleton as, I have noted, believed that all growers for different processors were indirectly in competition with each other and that the geographic market was Ireland. He expressed the view that because price competition on the downstream market impacted on the upstream markets (including that for broiler growing services) in effect growers on the entire island were competitors inter se. While there is no doubt that prices achieved on the downstream market will have their effects on all upstream markets I am not satisfied that such effects necessarily imply that the geographic area of the downstream market defines the area in which competition takes place in the provision of a broiler growing service. I believe the Plaintiffs assertion that the geographic market is one within a 15 mile radius of MPPs Plant is correct. There was no evidence that over time there was any real mobility (of those growers within that radius) between processors and there was evidence of the economic benefits, to grower and processor, of such a spatially limited market. Because the geographic market is defined in this way, it follows that it is a market in which there is only one purchaser of the service being provided and, as Dr Jacobson notes, that purchaser is, in an economist's language, a monopsonist. The next issue which arises is whether MPP occupies a dominant position in the relevant product market. a firm which has the position of a monopsonist has, as Stigler noted, the same power to control price in purchasing as a monopolist has in selling; a monopsonist however, the economic evidence suggests, only retains that power to control price and the power to behave independently of its competitors and customers where there are barriers to entry and exit the market in question. If it is easy to enter a market and the costs of entry can be recouped on exit then in such a contestable market the monopsonist is not necessarily dominant in that he cannot act independently of his competitors or customers without the risk of a "hit and run" operation whereby his price changes attract his competitors into the market. However, in the present case, the evidence suggests that the market is not contestable and that there are significant non strategic barriers to entry and exit from the market both for growers and processors alike. The failure of growers to exit the market in the face of a perceived decline in their margins and in the face of a perceived unfair pricing system is indicative of the high sunk costs they have and a lack of contestability of the market. It is of course not a breach of section 5 of the 1991 Act for MPP to have (as I find they have) a dominant position in the market: it is necessary for the Plaintiffs to establish that it has abused that position by the use of anti competitive practices which cannot be objectively justified. I have to decide whether any of MPP's practices complained of by the Plaintiff growers amount to an abuse of a dominant position by MPP.


(ii) ABUSE OF DOMINANCE - UNFAIR PURCHASE PRICES

74. In aid of their primary allegation that the flesh price offered by MPP was an unfair price, the Plaintiffs led evidence as to flesh prices paid to other growers, the flesh price offered by Cootehill Co-operative Society, the market price of meal sold by the designated millers, the price they sold it to MPP, and the price MPP sold the meal to growers. The Plaintiffs also had evidence as to the price of day olds charged by different processors and the generally declining gross margins of growers for MPP between 1991 and 1996. Apart from the evidence as to the Cootehill and MPP flesh prices, the only 'evidence' as to flesh prices paid by other processors was that contained in the questionnaire that had been drawn up by

75. Mr Quigley and apparently filled in by Mr Walsh of the IFA on behalf of other processors. Counsel for MPP did not object to the admissibility of the questionnaire replies but did submit that little, if any, weight should be attached to the evidence. I am satisfied that I should attach, little if any, any weight to responses to the questionnaire for the following reasons


(ii) Insofar as the answers are relied upon to establish that MPP is paying a price for flesh which is less than the economic value of the flesh, the answers do not support such a proposition looking only at the answers to para 14 of the questionnaire.
(iii) There are so many variables applicable to each processor as to render unreliable any conclusions as to the fairness or otherwise of any of the flesh prices offered by processors.

76. MPP next advanced the Cootehill flesh price as a basis for asserting MPPs flesh price is unfair. In my opinion the Cootehill price is not a proper basis for comparison because it emerged that the mechanism whereby Cootehill established its flesh price was one where most of the persons deciding the price were the beneficiaries of that decision. The Plaintiffs recognised that this price was not established on an "arm's length" basis but felt that the subtraction of 1p from the price cured that defect. I do not accept that it does cure the defect. If the price originally fixed is not an open market price, no arbitrary additions or subtractions can make it so.


77. Next the Plaintiffs contended that the "mark up" by MPP when they resold the meal to the growers was evidence of an unfair pricing system for the chicken flesh. Mr Magee's evidence was that between December 1991 and 1995 the price charged for meal was £266 per tonne whereas the cost to MPP was in the region of £210 per tonne during that period. While I accept that evidence, and its accuracy, I also accept the evidence of Mrs O'Driscoll that MPP did not make any profit on the meal and that the meal when charged at £266 p.t. resulted in the flesh price being "inflated" to 33p per lb. and that "one was compensated for in the other". She acknowledged, and I accept, that in the past Manor Mills Ltd had given a rebate of the order of £6 p.t. which was not passed on to growers until after December 1995. Professor Thom suggested that it was untenable for the Plaintiffs to assert that MPP should be able to assure the growers a "fair" return. I accept his evidence and in particular his analysis of the pre December 1995 price structure and the December 1995 proposal (see Table 1, ante) which seems to establish clearly that the proposed price structure - involving no mark up by MPP on meal - would not affect growers margins, this evidence also supports the evidence of Mrs O'Driscoll that one price was "compensated for in the other". The Plaintiffs further point to the declining margins of the MPP growers between 1992 and 1996 as evidencing an unfair pricing regime. I cannot accept that, even if it was a legitimate exercise to look at a representative grower's margin (i.e. the average margin over these 4 years), the margin to the grower is influenced solely or even to a significant extent by the flesh price paid to him. There are too many variables involved in the determination of the growers gross margin over time to allow a decline in the average gross margin to be attributed solely or primarily to unfair pricing. Finally, MPPs control over the price of day old chicks is advanced as evidence of unfair pricing. While the control certainly exists, it does not evidence unfairness in the pricing regime. In general terms, the Plaintiffs also point to the unilateral imposition of "deductions" as examples of what they regard as an inherently unfair system of price. I am satisfied that there is not evidence which as a matter of probability establishes that MPP have offered prices which are unfair and I am satisfied that the Plaintiffs have failed to establish a breach of section 5(2) (a) by adducing evidence either to satisfy the test adopted by the ECJ in United Brands supra or the test propounded in Bodson v Pompes Funetrees des Regions Libres , supra: no genuinely comparable flesh prices were adduced in evidence such as to allow the Court to make an assessment of the fairness of MPPs prices in accordance with the tests laid down in these cases..


(iii) ABUSE OF DOMINANCE: PURCHASE OF MEAL

78. The Plaintiffs suggest that MPP is guilty of abuse of dominance in obliging them to purchase their meal from MPP. They say that imposes on them an obligation which by its "nature or according to commercial usage" has no connection with the subject of such contracts. The evidence before the Court establishes beyond doubt that the practice of requiring growers to purchase their feed through their processor commenced in the 1960's; and that in 1976, MPP required its growers to purchase its meal through MPP, that, currently all processors (save Cootehill) require their growers to purchase meal through them. Similar "integration" exists in the United Kingdom. The prevalence of the practice over such a prolonged period of time leads me to the conclusion that the obligation to purchase meal through the processor is an obligation, which, as a result of commercial usage, has been connected with the contract for the provision of a broiler growing service. Even if I am wrong in reaching this conclusion, I believe that the obligation to purchase feedstuffs through the processor is not one which is capable of being characterised as a "supplementary obligation" which has "no connection" with the object of the contract rather it is one where there is a natural link between the meal and the growing chicken. As stated, the contract is one whereby a grower agrees to provide a broiler growing service for a processor who agrees to pay a price for the grown chicken. It is common case that the "quality of the feed determines the quality of the chicken". The processor, it seems to me, is perfectly entitled to specify how and with what particular feed the chicks, the subject of the contract, shall be reared. In so specifying, he is not in any way imposing an obligation which has "no connection" with the subject of the contract, namely, growing chickens. It seems to me that the foregoing characteristics of the broiler growing contract are such as to take it out of the prohibition in section 5(2) (d) of the 1991 Act. In any event I believe that the imposition of such an obligation as to feedstuffs can (unlike the supplementary obligations in Hilti and Tetra Pak 2 ) be objectively justified and in that regard I accept the evidence of Mr Truesdale and Mr Wilson that supermarkets and ultimate consumers expect "traceability" of product from raw materials through to chicken flesh. I accept also that the system of purchasing meal through MPP assists in achieving traceability and that were growers to purchase their own meal traceability would be "an administrative nightmare".


(iv) ABUSE OF DOMINANCE: PRICE DISCRIMINATION

79. While there was evidence that MPP offered different terms to different growers (the £5/25 deduction, the incentive of .5p per lb for new growers) there was no evidence to suggest that in fact such conduct had the result of placing the affected growers at any competitive disadvantage. In substance and in fact, this minimal price discrimination had no effect on competition in the market in question. Accordingly, I am satisfied that MPP has not abused its position of dominance and (if I am wrong in coming to such a conclusion) that any abuse of dominance can be objectively justified.


[B] SECTION 4 OF THE COMPETITION ACT 1991

80. The Plaintiffs alleged that their agreements with MPP have as their object or effect the restriction of competition by the imposition of unfair purchase prices and by requiring growers to purchase their meal through MPP. I am satisfied that the evidence does not sustain these allegations. There is no evidence that the objective of the broiler service contracts (either in stipulating the purchase of meal through MPP or in fixing prices) was to restrict competition either in the broiler growing market or, indeed, in the market for meal. I am equally satisfied that the agreements did not have this effect. No proper evidential basis was laid, as I have already indicated, for the allegation that MPP was guilty of fixing unfair prices. As to the question of requiring growers to purchase meal through MPP, even if it can be argued that such an obligation has the effect of restricting competition in the adjoining market for the sale of chicken feedstuffs there can be no doubt but that the restriction on competition can be objectively justified for the reasons already stated by me. Because it can be objectively justified, therefore, the restriction on the purchase of meal (looked at from either the broiler growing contract or the millers' contracts with MPP) does not fall foul of section 4. The application of a principle of "objective justification" to section 4 seems to be appropriate having regard to the reasoning in Metro (i) 1977 ECR 1875 and Metro (2) 1986 ECR 3021 referred to earlier.


81. Finally, the allegations of price discrimination by MPP has already been dealt with in relation to section 5: given that the discrimination has had no discernible effect on competition among growers no breach of section 4 has occurred.


[C] DEAD OR USELESS BIRDS

82. The Plaintiff growers allege that MPP were in breach of its contracts with them in failing to properly account to them in respect of deal and useless birds. I am satisfied that the Plaintiff growers have established as a matter of probability -


(a) That since late 1993 the veterinary officer at MPPs plant never left the kill line.
(b) That since that time the only birds classified by MPP as dead or useless were those condemned by the veterinary officer.
(c) That the Department of Agriculture record of condemnations is a correct record of birds condemned as dead and useless since late 1993.
(d) That the purchase notes and the REV 2 forms do not correctly record the dead and useless birds since late 1993
(e) That some birds classified as useless on REV 2 forms or purchase notes may have been processed in accordance with the production procedures manual.


© 1997 Irish High Court


BAILII: Copyright Policy | Disclaimers | Privacy Policy | Feedback | Donate to BAILII
URL: http://www.bailii.org/ie/cases/IEHC/1997/191.html