BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
Scottish Court of Session Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> Scottish Court of Session Decisions >> British Motor Trade Association v Gray [1951] ScotCS CSIH_3 (16 March 1951) URL: http://www.bailii.org/scot/cases/ScotCS/1951/1951_SC_586.html Cite as: [1951] ScotCS CSIH_3, 1951 SC 586, 1951 SLT 247 |
[New search] [Help]
16 March 1951
British Motor Trade Association |
v. |
Gray |
It is a fundamental principle of the law of interdict that the prayer of a petition craving interdict must be precise and definite in its terms, as the interlocutor following upon it must be precise and definite, so as to leave a respondent in no doubt about what he must or must not do. The prayer of this petition was criticised by the learned Dean of Faculty, who appeared for the respondent, as being neither precise nor definite, but, on the contrary, vague and uncertain in its language. If, the Dean of Faculty contended, the prayer were given effect to in an order of Court, the respondent would be left in serious doubt whether in his dealings in the purchase and sale of motor vehicles he was doing anything which might be construed as a breach of interdict. What, for example, was the respondent to understand that he was forbidden to do if he was interdicted from "facilitating the dealing with motor vehicles offered for sale or other disposal"? "Or other disposal," said the learned Dean, would include the making of a gift of a motor car to the respondent and would prohibit the respondent from accepting such a gift. Moreover, the prayer only referred to a person who offered a motor vehicle for sale. An interdict was binding according to its plain effect, and the Court should not sanction the interdict here craved, which was so vague and wide in its terms that it might easily be transgressed unwittingly and in ignorance of the true measure of liability it imposed. I observe that the prayer of the petition is an exact copy of the injunction granted by Roxburgh, J., in a case not unlike the present, British Motor Trade Association v. Salvadori, [1949] Ch. 566, at p. 572. It is not, if I may say so with respect, exactly a model, but it does not merit the description "vague and uncertain" applied to it by the Dean of Faculty. In my opinion, the language of the prayer is sufficiently plain and definite, and an interdict pronounced in terms of the prayer would leave the respondent in no doubt as to what he is forbidden to do. He could be under no misapprehension as to its scope. The respondent is a motor car dealer. He cannot be ignorant of the existence of such covenants. An interdict pronounced in terms of the prayer of the petition is a plain prohibition against his buying or otherwise dealing with any motor vehicle offered to him for sale or other disposal by a person known to the respondent to have executed a covenant in respect of that vehicle, and against his affording facilities for selling or otherwise disposing of it. Assuming, for the purposes of competency, that the restriction imposed by the covenant is a valid restriction, it is now well settled that a third party may be interdicted from inducing a person, who has contracted to be bound, by a valid restriction, to commit a breach of that restriction. In my opinion, the plea to the competency of the petition fails.
It was further argued by the learned Dean of Faculty that the covenant, being a covenant in restraint of trade, was an unenforceable contract and, in particular, that it was unenforceable against a stranger. It was out of the question to say that the owner of a motor car could be bound by any restriction in regard to the use or sale of the car, since it was well settled that restrictive conditions did not run with the goods. There was no attempt here to interdict the seller, or to enforce the restriction against him, and he was a party to the covenant. Afortiori, it could not be enforced against the respondent, who was not a party to the agreement. With great respect to the learned Dean, I think that the argument is misconceived. The gravamen of the charge made by the petitioners against the respondent is that he induced persons knowingly and intentionally, and without lawful justification, to breach the covenants which they had made with the petitioners. The respondent is not being sued on the contract between the covenantor and the covenantee; he is being sued for an actionable wrong in respect that, without justification, he has induced one of the parties to the covenant to commit a breach of his covenant, thereby causing damage to the other. The case of Lumley v. Gye, (1853) 2 E. & B. 216, established the proposition that a party who had made a contract with another was entitled to recover damages from a third party who had maliciously persuaded that other to break his contract. There the contract was one for personal service. But it was pointed out by Lord Macnaghten in Allen v. Flood, [1898] A C 1, at p. 153, that the subsequent cases of Bowen v. Hall, (1881) 6 Q. B. D. 333, and Temperton v. Russell, [1893] 1 Q B 715, are authorities for the proposition that the principle is not confined to contracts for personal service. These are cases decided in England, but it is equally the law of Scotland that each party to a lawful contract, whether for service or anything else, has a legal right to have it observed by the other, and the failure to perform it by the other is a wrong or injury done by him: and so is the corollary that anyone who wrongfully and knowingly procures a breach of a contract by one party to the injury of the other is liable to the party so injured in damages. Lord Macnaghten emphasised this in the House of Lords in Quinn v. Leathem, [1901] A C 495, when he said (at p. 510):
"Speaking for myself, I have no hesitation in saying that the decision [in Lumley v. Gye ] was right, not on the ground of malicious intention—that was not, I think, the gist of the action—but on the ground that a violation of legal right committed knowingly is a cause of action, and that it is a violation of legal right to interfere with contractual relations recognised by law if there be no sufficient justification for the interference."
In Crofter Hand Woven Harris Tweed Co. v. Veitch, 1942 S. C. (H. L.) 1, at p. 8, the Lord Chancellor (Viscount Simon) enunciated the principle in this simple formula:
"If C has an existing contract with A, and B is aware of it, and if B persuades or induces C to break the contract with resulting damage to A, this is, generally speaking, a tortious act for which B will be liable to A for the injury he has done him."
Accordingly, it seems to me that the respondent may be interdicted from inducing a covenantor to commit a breach of the restriction regarding the resale of the covenantor's motor car set forth in his covenant with the petitioners, if such a restriction is valid.
It is maintained, however, that the contract being in restraint of trade and unenforceable, the restriction is invalid. It is true, of course, that the petitioners must show that the restriction, which they have imposed, goes no further than is reasonable for the protection of their legitimate interests. "All interference with individual liberty of action in trading, and all restraints of trade of themselves, if there is nothing more," said Lord Macnaghten in Nordenfelt's case, [1894] A C 535, at p. 565, "are contrary to public policy, and therefore void. That is the general rule. But there are exceptions: restraints of trade and interference with individual liberty of action may be justified by the special circumstances of a particular case. It is a sufficient justification, and indeed it is the only justification, if the restriction is reasonable—reasonable, that is, in reference to the parties concerned and reasonable in reference to the interests of the public, so framed and so guarded as to afford adequate protection to the party in whose favour it is imposed, while at the same time it is in no way injurious to the public." The covenant here in question is in essence a price maintenance agreement devised (a) to protect the interests of the motor trade, (b) to prevent price inflation, and (c) to protect the purchasing public. Now, it is well settled that price maintenance agreements, if reasonable, are perfectly competent agreements. It is, in the last analysis, merely a question whether a man is entitled, when he is selling his own goods, to make a bargain as to the use to be made of them by the purchaser. That a man may make such a bargain was recognised by Lord Shaw in National Phonograph Co. of Australia v. Menck, [1911] A C 336, at p. 347, when he said:
"To begin with, the general principle, that is to say the principle applicable to ordinary goods bought and sold, is not here in question. The owner may use and dispose of them as he thinks fit. He may have made a certain contract with the person from whom he bought, and to such a contract he must answer."
I apprehend that the same right to make a bargain as to the use of goods by a purchaser effeirs to two or more men engaged in the manufacture and marketing of the same or similar goods; they, too, in combination are entitled to make bargains with the purchasers of their goods as to the price above or below which their goods shall not be sold. In Sorrell v. Smith, [1925] A. C. 700, it was laid down by the House of Lords that, if the real purpose of two or more persons combining to protect trade interests was to forward or defend the trade of all those combining, then no wrong was committed even although damage to another ensued, provided that the purpose was not effected by illegal means. In his speech, giving judgment in the Harris Tweed Co. case (cit. sup.), Lord Wright said (at p. 34):
"Two later cases show how far the Courts have gone in upholding the rights of persons to freedom to pursue their own interests in their trade even at the cost of seriously impeding the freedom in a practical sense of other persons in their trade. Perhaps the most striking case of this nature is Ware and de Freville, Limited v. Motor Trade Association, [1921] 3 K. B. 40, approved by this House in Sorrell's case, and later applied in Thorne v. Motor Trade Association, [1937] A. C. 797."
His Lordship, after explaining the circumstances in which the question arose in Ware and de Freville,continued:
"The scheme was a most ruthless and efficient system aimed at securing the mutual benefit of the associated traders at whatever loss or inconvenience to outsiders. The plaintiff complained that all he wanted was to exercise his lawful freedom to buy and sell cars as he desired. It was contended that the system adopted by the defendants went beyond any previous decision. The defendants, it was submitted, were saying, ‘If you continue to deal with the plaintiff you shall not only cease to deal with us but we shall take steps to prevent others dealing with you.’ But the Court of Appeal held that no legal wrong was committed, because the defendants had done nothing unlawful, and the combination was not a wrongful conspiracy, because its object was not to injure, but was the lawful object of promoting their business interests, as they understood them, by preventing price cutting and securing price maintenance. The elaborate system was devised solely with that object."
Lord Porter (at p. 51) summed up the matter thus:
"The confederates, millowners and defenders, had a common object of benefiting themselves and not of injuring the plaintiffs, and so must succeed in their defence."
I think that price inflation may cause just as much harm to the petitioners' legitimate interest to secure price maintenance as price cutting, and it seems to me that the petitioners are legally as much entitled to promote their business interests by preventing price inflation as they are by preventing price cutting. In my opinion, therefore, the petitioners have relevantly averred that their covenants with purchasers of new cars are for the purpose of defending their trade and promoting their business interests, and that the restrictive clause in the covenant is a valid restriction. It is part of the machinery for effectively working out a lawful object. It may be, to adopt Lord Wright's language, "a most ruthless and efficient" scheme; but, in my opinion, it does not go beyond what is reasonably required by the petitioners to secure their object.
Finally, it was argued that there was no relevant averment of inducement. It is true that the petitioners' averments do not say in so many words that the respondent induced any covenantor to commit a breach of his covenant. But the petitioners do say that the respondent knowingly bought vehicles from the retail purchaser by whom a covenant had been executed before the expiry of the covenant obligation. That seems to me to be a sufficient averment of inducement. As Mr Morison aptly said, "An offer to buy, provided the price offered is good enough, is an inducement to sell." Or, as Roxburgh, J., put it, succinctly and felicitously, in Salvadori (at p. 565):
"Any active step taken by a defendant having knowledge of the covenant by which he facilitates a breach of that covenant is enough. If this be so, a defendant by agreeing to buy, paying for, and taking delivery of a motor car known by him to be on offer in breach of covenant, takes active steps by which he facilitates a breach of covenant. … The covenantor who offers a car for sale is not unconditionally ready to break his covenant but only if the price is high enough and, accordingly, a defendant who offers such a price induces the seller to take the final step towards breaking his covenant by making his willingness to sell unconditional."
I would respectfully adopt the learned Judge's reasoning as my own; the conclusion he arrives at is unassailable.
In my opinion, the petitioners' averments are relevant and sufficient in law to support the prayer of their petition. On these averments they have relevantly set forth actings on the part of the respondent which constitute an infringement of their legal rights to the prejudice of their legitimate business interests. Furthermore, they aver that, in spite of warnings that his actings were an infringement of their rights, they have reason to believe that the respondent intends to continue acting in contravention of these rights and to the prejudice of their legitimate interests.
I shall, accordingly, repel the first and second pleas in law for the respondent, and allow to the parties a proof of their averments.
The respondent reclaimed, and the case was heard before the First Division (without Lord Carmont) on 11th and 12th January 1951.
At advising on 26th January 1951,—
It is unnecessary to rehearse the features of the scheme or the obvious evils which it was designed to frustrate. I single out from the petitioners' averments the salient points of their indictment against the respondent. He is a motor dealer in business in Glasgow, and therefore presumably familiar with the conditions under which the postwar market in cars is conducted. In February 1948 he was placed upon the Association's "stop list" by reason of his conduct in breach of the rules relating to price protection; and this involved that no member of the Association (which means no reputable car manufacturer, importer or dealer) would thereafter do business with him. Between April 1948 and November 1949 he knowingly purchased nine different vehicles in breach of current covenants prohibiting the sales,
one of the sellers who sold in breach of covenant being a person named Mark Hutchison. In addition, while acting in concert with Mark Hutchison, he knowingly purchased five further vehicles from Mark Hutchison in breach of current covenants. The full details regarding the acquisition of these fourteen cars will only be discovered at a proof, but the averments sufficiently disclose a deliberate course of conduct, pursued over an extended period, and involving the carrying on as a business venture of what I may describe as a "black market" in cars, in wilful defiance of the Association's covenant scheme. The acceptance of the respondent's argument would mean that the respondent and others like-minded to himself are entitled so to proceed, and that the law is powerless to interfere. I do not think that it is.
The main issues which emerged from the admirable arguments presented to us came to be reduced to two in number:—(1) Is the contract embodied in the covenant illegal as being in restraint of trade ? (2) Even if it is not, have the petitioners relevantly averred a good cause of action by Scots law ?
(1) On the first issue I feel that there is great force in the petitioners' contention that this is not a contract "in restraint of trade" in the sense in which that expression is used in our law. The typical contract in restraint of trade is a contract by which some restriction is imposed which tends to deprive the community of the labour, skill or talents of men in the employments or capacities in which they might be most useful to the public as well as to themselves, and which may be on that account contrary to public policy. Now the motor car covenant imposes no restraint upon any trader. It is a contract between trader and customer, and the customer is envisaged, not as a person who buys for resale by way of trade, but as a person who buys in order himself to use and consume the subject of sale. The only restraint imposed by the covenant is a restraint on such a customer, and the covenant is neither more nor less than an effort by the whole body of car manufacturers and dealers to ensure that, during the present emergency conditions of the market, they will only supply new cars to persons who will use them, and that they will not supply new cars to speculators who wish to turn them over at inflated prices. I am unable to hold that such a contract is in restraint of trade so far as the parties to the contract are concerned. It was urged however that the trade which was restrained was the trade of the general body of second-hand dealers in cars. To this the short answer is that no second-hand dealer is a party to the contract, and that the accepted rules dealing with contracts in restraint of trade have invariably been confined to the effect of the contract as between covenantor and covenantee and as regards the public at large. Doubtless it is an incidental (and deliberate) consequence of the taking of covenants from all purchasers of new cars that the second-hand market is pro tanto restricted; but that is a consequence—and in my view a beneficial consequence—of the policy adopted by the Association, and not a direct result of any individual contract.
Even if I am wrong in this, I consider that, viewed as a contract in restraint of trade, the covenant is not on that account illegal. The test may best be taken from the speech of Lord Macmillan in Vancouver Malt Co., where his Lordship was quoting from Lord Birkenhead, L.C., in M'Ellistrim:
"A contract which is in restraint of trade cannot be enforced unless (a) it is reasonable as between the parties; (b) it is consistent with the interests of the public."
I have heard nothing to show that the covenant does not fully satisfy both these conditions, and it is therefore enforceable as between the parties to it.
(2) The second issue raises at the outset a point of importance which the respondent felt unable to argue but to which nevertheless I desire to advert, viz., whether it is or may be an actionable wrong in Scotland for a third party to induce the breach of such a contract as that now in question. In England the answer is clearly in the affirmative; but in Scotland it so happens that until recently the only illustrations of the rule were found in relation to contracts of service, and the view has been hazarded that with us the doctrine is confined to the contract of service, and finds its origin in the primitive rights of property once recognised in the services of a servant, and originally in the servant or serf himself. But the rule is subjected to no such limitation as formulated in Glegg on Reparation; and in Findlay v. Blaylock the rule was extended to promise of marriage. Lord Normand said in general terms:
"It is no doubt true that, if a person, knowing that another person has a contractual relation with a third party, induces that person to break that contractual relation, he may be liable to the third party whose contract in consequence of his action is thereby breached. There are illustrations of that both in Scotland and in England,"
and his Lordship then went on to cite from one of the leading English decisions. Lord Fleming and Lord Moncrieff proceeded upon the same view. In Crofter Hand Woven Harris Tweed Co.several of the learned Lords, in dealing with a related question, assumed that the wider rule applied to Scotland. In these circumstances I am prepared to affirm expressly that it is only by accident that the Scottish illustrations have centred around the contract of service and the wrong of "harbouring servants," that these are only instances of the wider rule, and that on principle the wider rule, as more fully developed in England, must be considered as part of the law of Scotland. It remains to consider the precise form and limitations of the wider rule, for even our own decision of Findlay v. Blaylock shows that in some situations a third party may lawfully induce the breach of a contract between two other persons.
The classic pronouncement on the subject is in the speech of Lord
Macnaghten in Quinn v. Leathem, where he said that "a violation of legal right committed knowingly is a cause of action, and … it is a violation of legal right to interfere with contractual relations recognised by law if there be no sufficient justification for the interference." The rule was repeated in the same terms by Lord Haldane in Jasperson v. Dominion Tobacco Co. Its essence is to be found in knowing and unjustifiable interference. The application of this foundation principle to a case such as the present was discussed at length by Roxburgh, J., in the case of Salvadori, and I am content to adopt that learned Judge's observations mutatis mutandis. The suggestion that "sufficient justification" for the respondent's conduct can be found in his own self-interest seems to me to be manifestly untenable, for such an exception would empty the rule of all intelligible content. Equally it is plain as a matter of averment that the petitioners have a legal interest to claim the remedy which they seek in the fact that they are a trade union which is deeply concerned in maintaining and enforcing as uniformly as possible the scheme they have devised for the benefit of their members and of the public generally—indeed that the covenant scheme may fairly be described as their raison d'être—and that the respondent's efforts to break the scheme, if successful, must inevitably inflict damage upon them.
In these circumstances I consider that we should adhere to the interlocutor of the Lord Ordinary. But as the prayer, in terms of which an interim interdict is standing against the respondent, is not framed with the precision on which we are in use to insist in a decree for non-compliance with which grave consequences may ensue, I am of opinion that we should afford the petitioners an opportunity of proposing amended terms.
car in effect undertakes to the Association and to the dealer that for a period of twelve months from the date of purchase he will not use the car or permit its use for any purpose other than his private, professional or business purposes; and that he will not during that period dispose of it by sale, hire, or otherwise.
In their averments the Association explain how and why in August 1946 in the interests of their members and of the intending purchasers for use of new cars in the United Kingdom market they introduced the so-called "covenant scheme." It was introduced in an effort to prevent or discourage speculators from obtaining by purchase new cars and reselling them immediately at inflated prices to bona fidepurchasers for use in a market which was notoriously affected by scarcity of supply. It is, as I believe, a matter of common knowledge that prior to the introduction of the scheme the operations of speculators, who contrived to obtain new cars for immediate second-hand resale, had resulted in their obtaining from bona fidepurchasers for use very much higher prices than the manufacturers' listed price of similar new cars. Following the introduction of the covenant scheme, every retail purchaser of a new vehicle or chassis from an accredited dealer was required to enter into a covenant containing the undertaking aforesaid, and did so. In support of their plea that the respondent has engaged in actings which constitute the procuring by him of breaches of contract, the Association specifies (in articles 6 and 7 of the condescendence) fourteen instances of purchases by the respondent of vehicles, subject in each case to a covenant, prior to the expiry of the disposal time-limit. It is averred that the respondent participated in each of these transactions in the knowledge that the sale to him of the vehicles was made in breach of such a covenant, nine of such being purchased by himself alone, and the remaining five being purchases made by him from and in a course of dealing carried out by him in concert with another named person. The specification of these respective transactions is, in the circumstances averred, in my opinion, adequate to give fair notice to the respondent of the case sought to be made against him. The Lord Ordinary, having granted interim interdict, allowed to parties, after debate, a proof of their averments. That interlocutor is brought under review in this reclaiming motion, in which the respondent has submitted that the petition should be dismissed as irrelevant on one or other or both of those grounds viz.:—(a) that the covenants of which the respondent is alleged to have procured the several breaches are not enforceable in law because they are in restraint of trade; (b) that, estothat the covenants are enforceable, the averments by which it is sought to establish that the breach thereof was procured or induced by the respondent are not relevant to infer either that the respondent did so act or that, if he did so act, he perpetrated an actionable wrong.
With regard to the first submission—legal invalidity in respect of restraint of trade—I am of opinion that it is not well founded. The obligation on "the dealer," as a party to such a covenant, to obtain his purchaser's consent to grant the undertaking does not in the circumstances restrict or hamper that dealer's activities in effecting the sale of new vehicles. The only material restriction imposed on any of the parties is imposed on the purchaser who buys the vehicle for use and not for its commercial disposal by way of trade; and the limitation of the purchaser's freedom to deal, otherwise than by use, with the purchased vehicle endures only for twelve months. I am unable to discover any restraint of trade in the imposition by a seller of such a condition on the buyer of an article for use, and no case was cited in which such a condition, imposed in such circumstances on one who buys a chattel for use and not for commercial trading, has been held to amount to a restraint of trade. It was maintained, however, that the effect of such a covenant on the class of traders who deal in the second-hand car market is to restrict the number of vehicles coming into that market and so to operate as a diminution of the potential turnover available for those who deal in that market. It is true that each covenant, when complied with, results in the erection for twelve months of a barrier against a single vehicle's entry to the second-hand market; but cumulatively the twelve months' time-lag created in a year by the operation of covenants will reduce the potential inflow to the second-hand market during that year. Such reduction may to some extent be offset by the sale in the second-hand market of old cars belonging to those who have been successful in obtaining a new car and who for that reason are enabled to dispose of the old cars; but I agree that the net result will be to lessen the potential turnover in the market in which second-hand dealers trade. It thus appears that the Association's resort to the covenant scheme, as an integral part of its trade policy, does to a limited extent and for a limited period restrict the trade of the class of second-hand dealers. Even so, not every contract which restrains the trade of a relatively small group of traders is legally invalid and incapable of being enforced. If such a contract (1) is reasonable as between the parties to it, and (2) is consistent with the interests of the public, then it is enforceable. In my opinion the covenant under challenge complies with both those conditions. No second-hand dealer, as such, is a party to the covenant. The post-war scarcity of new cars available on the home market was and is such that manufacturers could have adopted a policy of selling to the highest bidder. The covenant scheme was calculated to ensure that new cars would be obtainable by bona fide purchasers for use, and not by speculators; and would be obtainable at a reasonable price. I am clearly of opinion that the scheme is reasonable as between the parties to the covenant in affording protection to the party in whose favour it is imposed and that it is at the same time in no way injurious to the public.
The second part of the reclaimer's argument was prefaced by counsel by an admission that by the law of Scotland an actionable wrong is committed by one who intentionally and without lawful justification induces or procures some one to break a contract made by him with another, if damage has resulted to that other, provided that the contract creates contractual relations recognised by law. The principle so stated is well established in the law of England and has been affirmed and applied frequently in English cases in the House of Lords. As has been pointed out by your Lordship, there have been few cases in Scotland in which such a principle has been applied and these have related to contracts of service; and it seems desirable that, before giving express judicial affirmation to its recognition as a general principle, we should consider the legal basis on which it rests. Your Lordship has reviewed the matter in the light of such Scottish authority as is available; and I agree with the conclusion at which your Lordship has arrived in affirming that the principle as stated is part of the law of Scotland. In that situation the question remains whether the Association's averments are relevant to infer that the respondent's actings were (1) intentional, (2) without lawful justification, (3) productive of damage to the Association, and (4) a procuring or inducement of the breach of the several covenants. I shall deal briefly with each of those elements. I am satisfied that the averments are relevant to infer a deliberate course of conduct pursued by the respondent, in the knowledge that the vehicles purchased by him were sold in breach of the covenant, and with the intention nevertheless of acquiring them—that is, intentionally. Further the only lawful justification suggested—self-interest based on his right to trade in the second-hand market—does not, in my opinion, amount to lawful justification. Moreover the partial defeat of the Association's covenant scheme, introduced for the benefit of its members and in the public interest, is prima facie prejudicial to the activities and the objects of the Association, and the averments of damage thereby caused, are, in my opinion, relevant for inquiry. Finally I am of opinion that the actings averred are relevant to infer a procuring or inducement of the breach of the several covenants that are alleged to have been broken. On this topic I am prepared respectfully to adopt the reasoning of Roxburgh, J., in the opinion delivered by him in Salvadori; and I agree with the Lord Ordinary in holding that the reasoning and the conclusion of Roxburgh, J., directed to a precisely similar topic, should be followed and applied in this case with the result of rejecting the reclaimer's argument against the relevancy of the averments in question.
I am therefore for refusing the reclaiming motion; and, subject to amending the terms of the interim interdict so as to make its content
more specific, as seems necessary, I am for adhering to the Lord Ordinary's interlocutor.
It was suggested that the plea of restraint of trade had no place here because it was a plea competent only to one of two contracting parties who had entered into a contract which operated to impose on one or other such a restraint. This may be, however, to limit too narrowly the ambit of the plea. It was competent for instance at common law to challenge the right of a trade union to take any action in the Courts to protect its property or rights on the ground that it was an illegal association at common law as being formed in restraint of trade. Why then is it not open to a third party to challenge a contract as a contract illegal for restraint of trade when he is sued for interfering with such a contract ? I should have thought that any illegal contract could be challenged by a person who was sued for procuring its breach and this seems to have been the view taken in De Francesco v. Barnum . I find it unnecessary, however, to answer this question because the contract in this case is not, in my opinion, bad for restraint of trade. It is, I consider, not only reasonable as between the parties to it but also consistent with the interests of the public and, indeed, I think positively in the interests of the public. Accordingly it is sufficient for the disposal of this case that the plea of restraint of trade fails on this ground.
As to proof of damage, it was conceded, I think rightly, that some damage must have been caused before an action for procurement of breach of contract can be raised, even if only an action of interdict. Damage in other words is of the essence of the wrong. But proof of specific damage is not required. Where breach of contract has been procured by a third party some damage will readily be inferred. An object of the Association here is to limit the price at which new cars may be sold by dealers to the public. If cars are resold, almost immediately after purchase, by members of the public, at greatly inflated prices, manufacturers and dealers are not going voluntarily to limit their selling prices. The natural and probable consequence is that they will withdraw from the Association, and regain freedom of bargaining power with the public or with each other, with inevitable damage to the Association. Whether this is the damage which the pursuers envisage I do not know. But it is sufficient that the pursuers have averred damage, albeit in general terms. They are entitled, in my opinion, to prove this averment.
The permission for BAILII to publish the text of this judgment
was granted by Scottish Council of Law Reporting and
the electronic version of the text was provided by Justis Publishing Ltd.
Their assistance is gratefully acknowledged.